Week 4: Readings Flashcards
Five mechanisms for the evolution of
cooperation.
Kin selection operates when the
donor and the recipient of an altruistic act are
genetic relatives.
Direct reciprocity requires repeated encounters between the same two individuals.
Indirect reciprocity is based on reputation; a helpful individual is more likely to receive help.
Network reciprocity means that clusters of cooperators outcompete defectors.
Group selection is
the idea that competition is not only between
individuals but also between groups.
Without any mechanism for the evolution
of cooperation, ___ dominate ___,
defectors dominate cooperators
alt. mechanisms of cooperators
“green beard” models where cooperators recognize each other via arbitrary labels (56–58).
Another way to obtain cooperation is making the game voluntary rather than obligatory: If players can choose to cooperate, defect, or not play at all, then some level of
cooperation usually prevails in dynamic oscillations (59).
conclusion
The two fundamental principles of evolution
are mutation and natural selection. But evolution
is constructive because of cooperation. New
levels of organization evolve when the competing units on the lower level begin to cooperate.
Cooperation allows specialization and thereby
promotes biological diversity. Cooperation is the
secret behind the open-endedness of the evolutionary process. Perhaps the most remarkable
aspect of evolution is its ability to generate cooperation in a competitive world. Thus, we
might add “natural cooperation” as a third fundamental principle of evolution beside mutation
and natural selection.
natural selection without cooperation mechanisms favors…
In any mixed population, defectors
have a higher average fitness than cooperators
(Fig. 1). Therefore, selection acts to increase
the relative abundance of defectors. After some
time, cooperators vanish from the population.
Remarkably, however, a population of only
cooperators has the highest average fitness,
whereas a population of only defectors has
the lowest. Thus, natural selection constantly
reduces the average fitness of the population
a cooperator is ….
a defector is…
reproduction can be…
A cooperator is someone who pays a cost,
c, for another individual to receive a benefit,
b. A defector has no cost and does not deal
out benefits. Cost and benefit are measured in
terms of fitness. Reproduction can be genetic
or cultural. I
Fisher’s fundamental theorem, which
states that…
average fitness increases under
constant selection, does not apply here because selection is frequency-dependent: The
fitness of individuals depends on the frequency (= relative abundance) of cooperators in
the population. We see that natural selection in well-mixed populations needs help for establishing cooperation (because NS alone would favor defectors).
Kin Selection
natural selection can favor cooperation if the
donor and the recipient of an altruistic act are
genetic relatives.
More precisely, Hamilton’s RULE
states that the coefficient of relatedness, r, must
exceed the cost-to-benefit ratio of the altruistic act:
r > c/b
Relatedness is defined as the probability of
sharing a gene. The probability that two brothers
share the same gene by descent is 1/2; the same
probability for cousins is 1/8. Hamilton’s theory
became widely known as “kin selection” or
“inclusive fitness”
*cooperation only among genetic relatives!
Direct Reciprocity
cooperation between unrelated individuals or even between members of different
species.
repeated encounters between the same
two individuals.
In every round, each player has
a choice between cooperation and defection. If I
cooperate now, you may cooperate later. Hence,
it might pay off to cooperate. “winning strategy”
was the simplest of all, tit-for-tat. This strategy always starts with a cooperation, then it
does whatever the other player has done in the
previous round: a cooperation for a cooperation, a defection for a defection. this helps with quickly building cooperation in a society with mainly defectors but is replaced with win-stay, lose-shift.
Tit-for-tat cannot correct mistakes, because an accidental defection leads to a long sequence of retaliation.
generous-tit-for-tat (17), a strategy that cooperates whenever you cooperate,
but sometimes cooperates although you have
defected [with probability 1 − (c/b)]. Natural
selection can promote forgiveness.
win-stay, lose-shift, which is the even simpler
idea of repeating your previous move whenever you are doing well, but changing otherwise.
RULE:
Direct reciprocity can lead to the
evolution of cooperation only if the probability,
w, of another encounter between the same two
individuals exceeds the cost-to-benefit ratio of
the altruistic act:
w > c/b
*Direct reciprocity relies on
repeated encounters between the same two
individuals, and both individuals must be able
to provide help, which is less costly for the
donor than it is beneficial for the recipient.
Indirect Reciprocity
used to explain interactions among humans are
asymmetric and fleeting. One person is in a
position to help another, but there is no possibility for a direct reciprocation. We help strangers
who are in need. We donate to charities that do
not donate to us.
indirect reciprocity is reputation
Helping someone establishes a good reputation, which will be rewarded by others. When
deciding how to act, we take into account the
possible consequences for our reputation.
where the same two individuals
need not meet again. One individual acts as
donor, the other as recipient. The donor can
decide whether or not to cooperate. The interaction is observed by a subset of the population who might inform others. Reputation
allows evolution of cooperation by indirect
reciprocity (19). Natural selection favors strategies that base the decision to help on the
reputation of the recipient
Indirect reciprocity has substantial cognitive
demands. Not only must we remember our own
interactions, we must also monitor the everchanging social network of the group. Language
is needed to gain the information and spread the
gossip associated with indirect reciprocity. Presumably, selection for indirect reciprocity and
human language has played a decisive role in
the evolution of human intelligence (28) reciprocity also leads to the evolution of morality
(30) and social norms (21, 22).
RULE:
Indirect reciprocity can
only promote cooperation if the probability, q,
of knowing someone’s reputation exceeds the
cost-to-benefit ratio of the altruistic act:
q > c/b
Network Reciprocity
real populations are not
well mixed
Spatial structures or social networks imply that some individuals interact
more often than others. One approach of capturing this effect is evolutionary graph theory
A cooperator pays a cost, c, for
each neighbor to receive a benefit, b. Defectors have no costs, and their neighbors receive
no benefits. In this setting, cooperators can
prevail by forming network clusters, where
they help each other. The resulting “network
reciprocity” is a generalization of “spatial reciprocity” (40).
RULE: he benefit-to-cost ratio must exceed the average number of neighbors, k, per individual: b/c > k
Group Selection
Selection acts not only on individuals but also
on groups. A group of cooperators might be
more successful than a group of defectors.
A simple model of group selection works as
follows (51). A population is subdivided into
groups. Cooperators help others in their own
group. Defectors do not help. Individuals reproduce proportional to their payoff. Offspring
are added to the same group. If a group reaches
a certain size, it can split into two. In this case,
another group becomes extinct in order to constrain the total population size. Note that only
individuals reproduce, but selection emerges
on two levels. There is competition between
groups because some groups grow faster and
split more often. In particular, pure cooperator
groups grow faster than pure defector groups,
whereas in any mixed group, defectors reproduce faster than cooperators. Therefore, selection on the lower level (within groups) favors
defectors, whereas selection on the higher level
(between groups) favors cooperators. This model
is based on “group fecundity selection,” which
means that groups of cooperators have a higher
rate of splitting in two. We can also imagine a
model based on “group viability selection,”where groups of cooperators are less likely to go
extinct.
In the mathematically convenient limit of
weak selection and rare group splitting, we obtain a simple result (51): If n is the maximum
group size and m is the number of groups, then
group selection allows evolution of cooperation,
provided that
b/c >1+(n/m)
Evolutionary Success
Without any mechanism for the
evolution of cooperation, defectors dominate. A
mechanism for the evolution of cooperation can
allow cooperators to be the evolutionarily stable
strategy (ESS), risk-dominant (RD), or advantageous (AD) in comparison with defectors.
Cooperators are ESS if they can resist invasion by
defectors
Cooperators are RD if the basin of
attraction of defectors is less than 1/2.
Cooperators are AD if the basin of attraction of
defectors is less than 1/3. In this case, the fixation probability of a single cooperator in a finite
population of defectors is greater than the inverse of the population size (for weak selection).
Some mechanisms allow cooperators to dominate defectors.
levels of miscommunication:
i. At 0% of miscmunication copycat wins.
ii. At 50% of miscomunication no one wins.
iii. Between 1-9% of miscomunication copykitten wins.
iv. Between 10-49% of miscomunication cheaters win.
o A little bit of miscomunication (1-9%) is fine because people forgive but too much miscomunication and it spreads distrust (10-49%).
three factors required for cooperation?
- REPEAT INTERACTIONS
Trust keeps a relationship going, but you need the knowledge of possible future repeat interactions before trust can evolve. - POSSIBLE WIN-WINS
You must be playing a non-zero-sum game, a game where it’s at least possible that both players can be better off – a win-win. - LOW MISCOMMUNICATION
If the level of miscommunication is too high, trust breaks down. But when there’s a little bit of miscommunication, it pays to be more forgiving.