Theme 3 - Labour markets Flashcards

1
Q

what is elasticity of labour supply

A

the responsiveness of labour supplied given a change in the wage rate

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

how does the nature of skills required in the job affect the elasticity supply of labour

A

🧠 Highly Skilled Jobs β†’ Inelastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Jobs requiring high-level qualifications (e.g. doctors, engineers, pilots) need years of education and training ➑️
πŸ”— The long time lag makes it difficult for workers to enter the profession quickly, even if wages rise ➑️
πŸ”— Therefore, the supply of labour is price inelasticβ€”a wage increase won’t immediately increase labour supply ➑️
πŸ”— This can cause persistent labour shortages in skilled sectors despite higher pay πŸ“‰πŸ‘©β€βš•οΈ

🧰 Low-Skill Jobs β†’ Elastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Jobs that require basic or minimal skills (e.g. retail, hospitality, warehouse work) have lower entry barriers ➑️
πŸ”— Many workers can be quickly trained or already possess the required skills, so they can switch jobs easily ➑️
πŸ”— This makes the labour supply more responsive to wage changes, i.e. more elastic ➑️
πŸ”— Firms in these sectors may find it easier to hire when wages rise πŸ›οΈ

πŸ•°οΈ Transferable Skills β†’ More Elastic Supply
πŸ”— If the skills required are general and transferable across industries (like communication or IT literacy)
πŸ”— Workers from other sectors can easily switch into these jobs without significant retraining
πŸ”— This increases the responsiveness of labour supply to wage changes
πŸ”— Making supply of labour more wage elastic πŸ§‘β€πŸ’»βž‘οΈπŸ§‘β€πŸ«

🧱 Specialist or Niche Skills β†’ Inelastic Supply
πŸ”— Some jobs require rare or specialised knowledge, e.g. nuclear engineers, patent lawyers
πŸ”— Very few workers are qualified, and training pipelines may be limited or expensive
πŸ”— Even large wage increases cannot quickly increase the number of suitable applicants
πŸ”— Resulting in a highly inelastic supply of labour in the short to medium term 🧬

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

how does the length of training affect the elasticity of supply of labour

A

⏳ Long Training Period β†’ Inelastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Jobs like doctors, architects, or airline pilots require many years of education and training
πŸ”— Even if wages rise, new workers can’t enter these jobs quickly due to long qualification times
πŸ”— This means the supply of labour responds slowly to changes in wage levels
πŸ”— As a result, the supply of labour is wage inelastic, especially in the short run πŸ“‰

πŸ§ͺ Professional Licensing Adds Time
πŸ”— Some careers also require passing professional exams or licensing (e.g. law, accounting, medicine)
πŸ”— These extra steps create additional barriers to entry for new workers
πŸ”— The longer and stricter the process, the slower the labour market can react to wage signals
πŸ”— This makes labour supply even more inelastic πŸ“‹

πŸ§‘β€πŸ« Short Training Period β†’ Elastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Jobs that need little to no formal training (like shop assistants or delivery drivers) can be entered quickly
πŸ”— A small rise in wages may attract many new workers, even from other sectors
πŸ”— Since new employees can be trained in a matter of days or weeks, supply can adjust rapidly
πŸ”— This makes the labour supply more elastic, especially in low-skill sectors πŸ“ˆ

πŸ” Retraining Time Affects Responsiveness
πŸ”— Even mid-skill jobs (like electricians or care workers) require some retraining time
πŸ”— If retraining is short and affordable, labour supply will be more responsive to wage changes
πŸ”— But if retraining is long, expensive or unavailable, fewer people will switch jobs
πŸ”— This reduces the elasticity of labour supply in those fields 🧰

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

how does vocation affect the elasticity of supply of labour

A

❀️ Strong Vocational Motivation β†’ Inelastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Jobs like teaching, nursing, or charity work often attract people with a strong sense of purpose or calling
πŸ”— These workers may stay in the job even if wages fall or don’t rise significantly
πŸ”— Their non-monetary motivation reduces their sensitivity to pay changes
πŸ”— This makes the supply of labour relatively inelastic πŸ“‰

πŸ’Έ Low Responsiveness to Wage Incentives
πŸ”— Because vocational workers are driven by job satisfaction, social impact, or moral duty
πŸ”— They are less likely to leave or enter the profession purely due to changes in wage levels
πŸ”— Even if pay improves, it might not attract large numbers of new workers without the same motivation
πŸ”— Therefore, wage changes have a limited impact on the labour supply β†’ inelastic πŸ“Š

πŸ§‘β€βš•οΈ High Retention Despite Poor Pay
πŸ”— Many vocational jobs are known for lower pay and higher emotional demands (e.g. NHS nurses, care workers)
πŸ”— Yet workers often remain committed, leading to lower turnover and stable labour supply
πŸ”— This reduces the responsiveness of labour supply to higher wages elsewhere
πŸ”— Again, this results in a wage inelastic supply of labour πŸ§β€β™€οΈπŸ§β€β™‚οΈ

🌱 Limits Pool of Potential Workers
πŸ”— Vocation-driven roles may only appeal to a small segment of the labour market
πŸ”— If few people are willing to take on emotionally taxing or mission-led jobs, the supply is limited
πŸ”— So even large wage rises may not increase supply much, as it’s the nature of the job, not pay, that matters
πŸ”— This restricts elasticity and keeps supply price inelastic 🧠

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

how does time affect the elasticity of labour supply

A

⏱️ Short Run β†’ Inelastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— In the short run, people can’t easily change careers, gain qualifications, or relocate for jobs
πŸ”— Even if wages rise, workers can’t respond quickly due to commitments or lack of training
πŸ”— As a result, the supply of labour stays fairly fixed in the short term
πŸ”— This makes the labour supply wage inelastic in the short run πŸ“‰

πŸ“† Long Run β†’ More Elastic Supply of Labour
πŸ”— Over the long run, workers have time to acquire skills, retrain, or move location for better-paying jobs
πŸ”— This means they are more able to respond to wage changes
πŸ”— Firms offering higher wages will attract more workers, even from different sectors
πŸ”— So, labour supply becomes more elastic in the long term πŸ“ˆ

πŸ“š Time Allows for Education and Training
πŸ”— If a job requires specialised skills, workers need time to complete courses or qualifications
πŸ”— These things can’t happen overnight, but are possible in the long run
πŸ”— As more workers qualify, the labour supply increases
πŸ”— So over time, the elasticity of supply improves, especially for skilled jobs πŸŽ“

🚚 Time to Relocate or Adjust Lifestyle
πŸ”— People might be willing to move to a new city or region for higher wages
πŸ”— But relocation takes time due to housing, family, or financial issues
πŸ”— In the long run, these barriers are easier to overcome
πŸ”— This makes labour supply more responsive and elastic over time 🌍

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

characteristics of a perfectly competitive labour market

A
  • there are many potential workers and employers
  • labour is homogenous, there is no difference in skills and qualifications between workers
  • there is perfect information for both workers and firms
  • firms are wage takers, they have no control over wages that they can over to their workers
  • there are no barriers to entry/exit
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

why do wage differentials exist

A

πŸŽ“ Differences in Skill Levels
πŸ”— Higher-skilled workers (e.g. surgeons, engineers) have rare and valuable expertise
πŸ”— These jobs have lower supply due to long training periods and high entry barriers
πŸ”— Employers are willing to pay more to attract and retain such workers
πŸ”— This leads to higher wages compared to low-skilled roles with high labour supply πŸ’°

πŸ§‘β€πŸ­ Differences in Working Conditions
πŸ”— Jobs that involve danger, stress, or unsociable hours (e.g. miners, offshore workers) are less desirable
πŸ”— Fewer people are willing to do them, so the labour supply is limited
πŸ”— Employers offer higher wages as a financial incentive to attract workers
πŸ”— This explains compensating wage differentials β˜’οΈβ›οΈ

πŸ•’ Differences in Labour Market Power
πŸ”— Workers in strong trade unions or monopsonistic markets can negotiate better pay
πŸ”— Similarly, some employers have more market power and can suppress wages
πŸ”— This causes wage differences between equally skilled workers in different sectors or regions
πŸ”— Resulting in inequitable wage differentials due to power imbalances βš–οΈ

🧬 Differences in Productivity
πŸ”— Some workers are more productive due to experience, talent, or better tools
πŸ”— Employers value higher output, so they’re willing to pay these workers more
πŸ”— More productive sectors (like tech or finance) also tend to pay more
πŸ”— So wage differentials reflect differences in marginal productivity βš™οΈ

🌍 Regional and Industry Differences
πŸ”— Cost of living and economic activity vary by region (e.g. London vs Wales)
πŸ”— Some industries (like investment banking) generate more revenue per worker
πŸ”— These differences affect the willingness and ability of firms to pay high wages
πŸ”— Leading to geographical and sectoral wage differentials πŸ™οΈ

πŸšͺ Discrimination and Social Factors
πŸ”— Gender, ethnic, or age discrimination may cause unjustified pay gaps
πŸ”— Even with equal skills and experience, some groups may be paid less
πŸ”— This skews wage distribution and limits fair access to higher-paying jobs
πŸ”— Leading to discriminatory wage differentials πŸ‘©πŸ½β€πŸ’Ό

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

another word for labour productivity

A

MRP

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

what is a monospony

A

a single dominant buyer of labour in a given profession
- they reduce wages and reduce quantity of labour

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

examples of monopsonies

A
  • government is a monpsony of nursing, teaching
  • supermarkets with farmers
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

features of monopsonies

A
  • wage makers, they set wages
  • ## will maximise revenue made from workers by hiring up to where MRP = MCl
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

why dont monopsonies employ more workers

A

πŸ’· They Have to Raise Wages for All Workers
πŸ”— In a monopsony, hiring one extra worker means paying a higher wage to all existing workers
πŸ”— This makes the marginal cost of labour (MCL) rise faster than the wage rate itself
πŸ”— So, employing more workers becomes increasingly expensive per unit of labour
πŸ”— To minimise costs, the firm chooses to employ fewer workers than in a competitive market πŸ’Έ

πŸ“Š Profit Maximisation at MC = MRP
πŸ”— A monopsony hires workers up to the point where MCL = MRP (Marginal Revenue Product)
πŸ”— Since MCL > wage, the employment level is lower than the socially efficient outcome
πŸ”— Even if they could hire more workers at the same wage, doing so would cut into profits
πŸ”— So, they restrict employment to maintain a higher profit margin πŸ“ˆ

πŸ§‘β€πŸ€β€πŸ§‘ Lack of Competitive Pressure
πŸ”— In competitive labour markets, firms must offer higher wages to attract workers
πŸ”— But monopsonies often face little or no competition for workers in the local area
πŸ”— This reduces the incentive to offer better pay or hire more staff
πŸ”— Result: low wages and lower employment than socially optimal 🀝

🧱 Barriers to Entry and Worker Mobility
πŸ”— Monopsonies often operate in areas where workers have limited alternatives (e.g. rural towns)
πŸ”— Since workers can’t easily move away or switch industries, the firm can dominate hiring
πŸ”— The monopsony takes advantage of this by keeping wages low and hiring fewer people
πŸ”— This leads to labour market inefficiency and underemployment 🚧

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

why does supply = AC on a monopsony diagram

A
  • because it shows the wage rate necessary to attract each additional worker, which is the average cost of hiring labo
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

average cost of labour equation

A

total cost of labour/quantity of labour

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

what is a trade union

A

an organisation of workers who bargain for higher wages and better working conditions
- a monopoly of labour
- increases wages of workers

  • Unions often negotiate contracts protecting workers from unfair dismissal dismissal, providing greater job security.
  • Unions advocate for improved workplace health and safety standards
  • Unions negotiate for reasonable working hours, rest breaks, and family-friendly policies
  • Unions often provide or advocate for access to training and professional development opportunities, helping workers to enhance their skills and career prospects.
  • Unions give workers a collective voice, allowing them to participate in decision-making processes
  • unions help reduce employee turnover,
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

advantages of trade unions

A

πŸ’Έ Higher Wages for Workers
πŸ”— Trade unions bargain collectively on behalf of many workers
πŸ”— This gives them more negotiating power than individuals would have
πŸ”— Employers may offer higher wages to avoid strikes or maintain productivity
πŸ”— Result: Workers enjoy better pay and job satisfaction πŸ’°

πŸ§‘β€βš–οΈ Improved Working Conditions
πŸ”— Unions campaign for safer, fairer, and more humane working conditions
πŸ”— This can include reasonable hours, safety regulations, and breaks
πŸ”— Firms improve conditions to avoid legal issues or industrial action
πŸ”— Leads to better health, wellbeing, and morale in the workplace πŸ› οΈ

πŸ§‘β€πŸ« Training and Skill Development
πŸ”— Some unions help workers access education, training, and upskilling
πŸ”— This improves workers’ productivity and employability over time
πŸ”— Employers benefit from a more skilled workforce
πŸ”— Boosts both wages and long-run economic growth πŸ“ˆ

πŸ›‘οΈ Protection Against Exploitation
πŸ”— Unions represent workers in disputes over unfair dismissal, discrimination, or unsafe practices
πŸ”— This helps protect vulnerable employees who may not have legal knowledge or confidence
πŸ”— Employers are encouraged to follow rules and treat staff fairly
πŸ”— Promotes justice and equality in the labour market βš–οΈ

πŸ“£ Voice in Decision-Making
πŸ”— Unions act as a channel of communication between employees and management
πŸ”— Workers’ concerns are more likely to be heard and addressed
πŸ”— This can reduce conflict and improve trust and cooperation in the workplace
πŸ”— Encourages long-term stability and productivity 🧩

17
Q

disadvantages of trade unions

A

βš”οΈ Risk of Industrial Action (Strikes)
πŸ”— Unions may call for strikes or go-slows during disputes, disrupting services
πŸ”— This can lead to economic losses and inconvenience to the public
πŸ”— For example, during the 2023 NHS nurses’ strikes, patients faced cancelled operations and delays
πŸ”— Strikes can damage the reputation of industries and reduce output ❌πŸ₯

πŸ’· Increased Labour Costs for Firms
πŸ”— Unions often push for higher wages and better benefits
πŸ”— This can increase a firm’s variable costs and reduce profits
πŸ”— For example, Royal Mail faced union demands for pay rises during inflation, worsening financial strain
πŸ”— Firms may respond by cutting jobs, automating, or relocating πŸ’ΈπŸ“‰

🧱 Reduced Flexibility in the Labour Market
πŸ”— Strong unions may resist changes to contracts, hours, or job roles
πŸ”— This reduces a firm’s ability to respond quickly to market changes
πŸ”— In the London Underground, union resistance delayed changes to night tube working hours
πŸ”— It can limit innovation and slow modernisation efforts 🐌

πŸ§‘β€πŸ€β€πŸ§‘ Wage-Push Inflation
πŸ”— If unions are too powerful, repeated wage increases may raise overall production costs
πŸ”— Firms pass these costs onto consumers through higher prices
πŸ”— This occurred in the 1970s UK economy, where strong union activity contributed to inflation
πŸ”— Leads to less competitive exports and reduced purchasing power πŸ“ˆπŸŒ

βš–οΈ Unfair Power Dynamics in Public Sector
πŸ”— Unions in the public sector (e.g. teachers or junior doctors) may have more leverage due to essential service status
πŸ”— The government may feel pressured to concede even when budgets are tight
πŸ”— Taxpayers bear the cost of settling demands rather than investing elsewhere
πŸ”— This creates inefficiency and fiscal pressure πŸ’ΌπŸ§Ύ

18
Q

how do trade unions help in a monopsony market

A

πŸ’· Raising Wages Above Monopsony Exploitation
πŸ”— In a monopsony (e.g. a dominant employer like Amazon in a rural area), firms set low wages due to limited competition for labour
πŸ”— Trade unions can bargain collectively, giving workers greater negotiating power
πŸ”— This can raise wages closer to the worker’s marginal revenue product (MRP)
πŸ”— Helps correct wage exploitation, reducing the gap between what workers are paid and what they’re worth πŸ’°

πŸ§‘β€πŸ€β€πŸ§‘ Increasing Employment to Socially Optimal Levels
πŸ”— Monopsonists hire fewer workers because marginal cost of labour (MCL) > wage rate
πŸ”— A union-set wage can flatten the MCL curve, making it constant up to a certain employment level
πŸ”— This encourages the firm to hire more workers, moving employment closer to a competitive equilibrium
πŸ”— Leads to greater labour market efficiency and output πŸ“Š

πŸ›‘οΈ Protecting Workers from Abuse or Exploitation
πŸ”— In monopsony markets, workers may fear dismissal or unfair treatment with no alternative employer nearby
πŸ”— Trade unions provide legal support, grievance handling, and job security
πŸ”— This reduces the employer’s bargaining power advantage
πŸ”— Encourages fairer treatment and reduces worker exploitation πŸ§Ύβš–οΈ

πŸ“£ Giving Workers a Voice
πŸ”— Monopsony firms may make unilateral decisions about pay or working conditions
πŸ”— Trade unions represent worker interests in negotiations and policy-making
πŸ”— This creates a more balanced relationship between employer and employee
πŸ”— Can improve morale, productivity, and long-run trust within the workplace πŸ—£οΈπŸ€

19
Q

how does the strength of trade unions affect trade union power

A

πŸ‘₯ Membership Size and Density
πŸ”— A stronger union typically has more members and higher density in a sector
πŸ”— This gives the union more bargaining power, as employers cannot easily ignore a large, unified group
πŸ”— With widespread support, threats of strikes or collective action become more credible
πŸ”— Leads to higher wages or better conditions being secured for more workers πŸ“ˆ

βš–οΈ Legal Rights and Government Support
πŸ”— The strength of a union is partly determined by the legal framework it operates in
πŸ”— If laws support collective bargaining and strike action (e.g. some Nordic countries), unions have greater influence
πŸ”— In contrast, in the UK post-1980s, anti-union legislation weakened union power
πŸ”— Stronger legal backing allows unions to negotiate more effectively 🧾

🧱 Centralisation and Organisation
πŸ”— Strong unions tend to be highly organised and centralised, with clear leadership and structure
πŸ”— This allows for coordinated actions, such as national strikes or industry-wide negotiations
πŸ”— It increases the union’s ability to influence policy and employer decisions
πŸ”— Results in stronger protections and more consistent gains for members 🧠

πŸ” Economic Context and Employer Dependence
πŸ”— Union strength is also influenced by economic conditions and industry type
πŸ”— In essential services (e.g. healthcare, transport), unions are harder to replace, giving them more power
πŸ”— But in fragmented or gig-based sectors (like Uber drivers), weak structure means limited power
πŸ”— Stronger unions emerge where employers rely heavily on skilled, unionised labour πŸš‰

20
Q

what is trade union density

A

the proportion of the workforce in a given profession that are part of a given trade union

21
Q

what is a union mark

A

the difference between the wages that people in a trade union are getting vs the ones who arent (in a similar profession). the bigger the difference, the bigger the success of the trade union

22
Q

real world evidence that proves that the power of trade unions are limited

A

legislation from the 1970s:
- β€œclosed shop” trade unions being banned, reduces power of individual trade unions
- for strikes, ballots have to be done in secret, and they can only take place if at least 70% of the union agree to strike
- you’re only allowed to strike against your own employer, this reduces the power of the strike

23
Q

what are closed shop trade unions

A
  • In a closed shop arrangement, employers agree to hire only union members, and employees must remain union members to continue working at the company.
  • The union has significant control over the hiring process, as non-union members cannot be employed.
24
Q

why has the union density in the UK decreased?

A

🏭 Structural Changes in the Economy
πŸ”— The UK economy has shifted from manufacturing and heavy industry (where unions were strong)
πŸ”— Toward a service-based economy (like retail, hospitality, and IT), where union presence is traditionally weaker
πŸ”— Service sector jobs are often part-time, temporary, or individualised, making union organisation harder
πŸ”— As a result, union density has fallen because fewer workers are in traditionally unionised sectors 🏒

βœ‚οΈ Government Legislation and Policies
πŸ”— From the 1980s onwards, UK governments (especially under Thatcher) introduced laws restricting union power
πŸ”— Policies like making strike action harder, requiring secret ballots, and allowing fines for illegal strikes weakened unions
πŸ”— These restrictions made unions less effective in protecting workers’ rights, reducing their appeal
πŸ”— As union power diminished, fewer workers saw the benefits of joining, lowering union density

πŸ”„ Changing Nature of Employment Contracts
πŸ”— The rise of zero-hour contracts, freelance work, and gig economy jobs has fragmented the workforce
πŸ”— Workers on flexible contracts often have less job security but also less collective identity with coworkers
πŸ”— It’s harder for unions to organise and represent individuals working under such isolated conditions
πŸ”— This trend has weakened traditional union structures, leading to a fall in membership

🧠 Changing Worker Attitudes
πŸ”— Younger generations of workers often see unions as less relevant to modern working life
πŸ”— Many workers focus more on individual career development rather than collective bargaining
πŸ”— In some sectors (like tech or finance), workers feel empowered individually and don’t see the need for union protection
πŸ”— This shift in workplace culture has contributed to a decline in union density over time

πŸ’· Employer Resistance
πŸ”— Many employers now actively discourage unionisation, offering direct negotiation, individual bonuses, or workplace councils instead
πŸ”— By promoting alternative forms of employee representation, firms reduce workers’ perceived need for unions
πŸ”— Anti-union tactics and promotion of a non-unionised culture weaken union influence
πŸ”— As a result, fewer workers are encouraged to join unions, causing a drop in union density

25
why do men get paid more than women
βš–οΈ Gender Discrimination in Hiring and Pay πŸ”— Gender biases can influence hiring and pay decisions, often favouring men for higher-paying roles πŸ”— Men are often overrepresented in high-paying industries like finance or tech πŸ”— Women may be overlooked for promotion opportunities or higher-paying positions πŸ”— Leads to a pay gap as women are often stuck in lower-paying sectors or roles πŸ‘¨β€πŸ’ΌπŸ‘©β€πŸ’Ό πŸ’Ό Occupational Segregation πŸ”— Men and women tend to work in different occupations due to social norms or career choices πŸ”— Men are often in higher-paying, male-dominated fields, while women are more represented in care or teaching roles πŸ”— These fields tend to have lower average wages than male-dominated industries πŸ”— The result is a gender pay gap where men earn more on average due to industry disparity πŸ’πŸ‘©β€πŸ« πŸ‘Ά Childcare and Career Interruptions πŸ”— Women are more likely to take career breaks or work part-time for childcare responsibilities πŸ”— These breaks can lead to career stagnation, fewer opportunities, and less experience over time πŸ”— Men, typically less likely to take career breaks, can advance in their careers more quickly πŸ”— This disrupts women's earning potential and contributes to the overall gender pay gap πŸ‘ΆπŸ§‘β€πŸ‘©β€πŸ‘§β€πŸ‘¦ πŸ’΅ Negotiation and Salary Transparency πŸ”— Research suggests that men are more likely to negotiate their salaries, while women are less likely to ask for higher pay πŸ”— Without proper salary transparency or union backing, employers may offer lower starting salaries to women πŸ”— This sets women on a lower wage trajectory, even if their job responsibilities are similar to men's πŸ”— Leads to a persistent pay gap over the course of their career πŸ“‰ πŸ“ˆ Implicit Bias in Promotions and Performance Evaluation πŸ”— Women may face implicit biases in performance reviews and promotions πŸ”— Men are often rated higher in terms of leadership qualities or job performance, even when women do the same work πŸ”— This leads to lower promotions or salary increases for women compared to their male counterparts πŸ”— Men's earnings increase faster, leading to a widening gender pay gap over time πŸ“Š
26
why do footballers get paid more than teachers
πŸ“ˆ Market Demand and Revenue Generation πŸ”— Football clubs generate huge revenue from ticket sales, broadcasting rights, and sponsorships πŸ”— These revenues allow clubs to offer higher salaries to attract top talent πŸ”— Football is a global industry, with massive demand and audience size, especially for big clubs like Real Madrid or Manchester United πŸ”— Footballers earn a larger proportion of the income they help generate compared to teachers πŸ’Έβš½ 🌍 Global Market and Talent Pool πŸ”— Footballers are part of a global market with limited spots in top-tier teams, making their skills more scarce and valuable πŸ”— Clubs compete to attract the best talent, leading to higher wages as the price of skilled players increases πŸ”— In contrast, the demand for teachers is more stable and widespread,whilst supply is larger meaning individual teachers are less valuable in terms of scarcity πŸ”— Leads to footballers earning much more due to their unique market position 🌎 πŸ† Entertainment Industry Premium πŸ”— Football is part of the entertainment and sports industry, where stars are marketed for their appeal and celebrity status πŸ”— High-profile footballers bring in sponsorship deals, merchandise sales, and commercial deals πŸ”— This provides additional income that doesn't rely on their club's revenue alone πŸ”— Teachers, while essential, are not marketed or commercialised in the same way, limiting their earning potential πŸŽ¬πŸ’Ό πŸ” Performance-Based Earnings vs. Set Salaries πŸ”— Footballers earn through performance-based contracts and bonus systems for goals, assists, or winning titles πŸ”— This creates the potential for higher earnings if the player performs well or brings in more fans and revenue πŸ”— Teachers typically have fixed salaries, regardless of their individual performance or results πŸ”— Footballers' salaries are more variable, and in top leagues, extremely high due to performance incentives πŸ…πŸ’₯ πŸ… Short Career Span in Football vs. Long-Term Stability in Teaching πŸ”— Footballers often have a short career span (around 10–15 years), meaning they need to earn more while they are playing πŸ”— Their relatively short working life means their lifetime earnings must be much higher to sustain them after retirement πŸ”— Teachers can have a longer career (30–40 years), but earn less overall because their pay is spread over a longer duration πŸ”— This contributes to the disparity in salaries, as footballers are compensated for their shorter earning window ⏳⚽
27
why do Londoners get paid more than northerners
πŸ™οΈ Agglomeration Economies London benefits from agglomeration economies, where businesses cluster together ➑️ This boosts productivity, innovation, and access to skilled labour ➑️ Higher productivity means workers generate more value per hour ➑️ ⏩ Firms can afford to pay higher wages to attract and retain skilled staff πŸ’Ό Higher Concentration of High-Skill, High-Wage Industries London is home to industries like finance, law, and tech, which offer high salaries ➑️ These sectors demand highly skilled workers, who are in limited supply ➑️ To compete for talent, firms pay premium wages ➑️ ⏩ This pulls the average wage in London above that of other UK regions 🏠 Higher Cost of Living London has significantly higher housing, transport, and childcare costs ➑️ Employers offer London Weighting or higher base pay to compensate ➑️ Without this, workers may be unable to afford to live there ➑️ ⏩ This artificially raises wages compared to lower-cost Northern areas πŸŽ“ Greater Access to Education and Opportunities London offers access to top universities, training schemes, and global firms ➑️ This improves skills, experience, and employability of its workforce ➑️ More skilled workers tend to command higher wages in the labour market ➑️ ⏩ This leads to a widening regional wage gap over time πŸ›« Global City Status and Foreign Investment As a global financial hub, London attracts multinational firms and FDI ➑️ These firms bring capital, jobs, and international salaries ➑️ To compete globally, they offer high wages to meet international standards ➑️ ⏩ Boosts London pay far above many domestic regions
28
why do some ethnic groups get paid less than others
βš–οΈ Discrimination and Bias in the Labour Market πŸ”— Racial discrimination can lead to ethnic minorities being offered lower wages for the same roles or qualifications πŸ”— Employers may have unconscious biases that favour certain ethnic groups over others in hiring or pay decisions πŸ”— This creates a pay gap between ethnic groups, as people of certain ethnicities may face unjust barriers to higher-paying jobs πŸ”— Discriminatory hiring practices lead to lower overall earnings for certain ethnic groups πŸ“‰πŸ‘₯ πŸ§‘β€πŸ« Differences in Educational Attainment and Access πŸ”— Some ethnic groups may have less access to quality education, leading to lower qualifications on average πŸ”— This can result in a lower starting wage or fewer opportunities for higher-paying jobs πŸ”— Structural inequalities in education or social mobility can limit the earning potential of certain ethnic groups πŸ”— This contributes to a wage gap where groups with lower access to education earn less πŸ“šπŸŽ“ 🌍 Segregation in Low-Wage Sectors πŸ”— Ethnic minorities are often overrepresented in lower-wage sectors, such as hospitality, retail, or manual labour πŸ”— These industries generally offer lower pay and fewer opportunities for career progression πŸ”— Many ethnic groups face fewer opportunities to move into higher-paying roles or industries πŸ”— This occupational segregation contributes to persistent wage inequalities πŸ’ΌπŸ¬ πŸ™οΈ Geographical Factors and Economic Opportunities πŸ”— Ethnic minorities are more likely to live in economically disadvantaged areas, where job opportunities may be more limited πŸ”— This reduces access to higher-paying jobs, as employers in lower-income regions may pay less πŸ”— Additionally, ethnic minorities may face higher unemployment rates or difficulty finding stable work πŸ”— These factors combine to contribute to lower wages in disadvantaged ethnic communities πŸšοΈπŸ“ πŸ“Š Unequal Access to Networks and Social Capital πŸ”— Many high-paying job opportunities are obtained through personal networks or social capital πŸ”— Some ethnic groups may not have the same professional networks or access to industry connections πŸ”— This makes it harder for certain groups to access job opportunities or mentorship that can lead to higher wages πŸ”— As a result, ethnic minorities may find themselves underpaid or overlooked for career-advancing positions πŸ“±πŸ€ πŸ§‘β€πŸ€β€πŸ§‘ Structural Barriers in Promotion and Career Advancement πŸ”— Even when ethnic minorities are employed in the same roles as their counterparts, they may face fewer promotion opportunities πŸ”— Implicit bias in performance evaluations or leadership positions may limit advancement prospects for certain ethnic groups πŸ”— Lack of mentorship or career development programs tailored to minorities can also affect career progression πŸ”— This leads to lower wages due to fewer promotions or advancement in their career πŸ’πŸ“‰
29
microeconomic advantages of trade unions
1. higher wages : - Trade unions negotiate higher wages for their members through collective bargaining. - This leads to increased earnings for members in the union - Higher wages improve workers' standard of living and increase their spending power. - Increased consumer spending can boost demand in the economy, potentially driving business growth. 2. Increased efficiency: - Trade unions advocate for better working conditions, such as safety standards and reasonable working hours. - A healthier, more satisfied workforce tends to be more productive and efficient - Increased productivity can lower production costs for businesses and improve overall efficiency. 3. Job security: - Trade unions negotiate contracts that often include job security provisions. - Greater job security reduces the risk of sudden layoffs for workers - Reduced uncertainty about employment can increase worker morale and long-term commitment to the company - This stability can foster better long-term relationships between workers and employers, potentially improving business performance.
30
microeconomic disadvantages of trade unions
- wage increases can increase labour costs for firms (fixed cost) - higher labour costs may lead to firms laying off workers or substituting labour for capital. this can increase supply of inactive workers - with increased wage costs, firms may allocate less budget towards innovation - lower supernormal profits - this may reduce productivity growth and might reduce the firms dynamic efficiency, - increased wages can increase COL , may be passed onto consumers and reduce the firms competitiveness in the market - union rules often limit layoffs and mandate specific hiring practices, reducing firms’ ability to quickly adjust labour to demand fluctuations - this inflexibility can lead to inefficiencies in labour allocation,increasing operational costs and slowing response times to market changes - higher wages are not always matched by productivity increases, leading to a wage-productivity imbalance - the gap can reduce profit margins and inhibit reinvestment,hindering long term growth and efficiency
31
evaluation points for microeconomic effects of trade unions
πŸ’ͺ It depends on the strength of the trade union Stronger trade unions with high membership can bargain more effectively ➑️ This increases their ability to negotiate higher wages and better conditions ➑️ But if the union is weak or fragmented, employer resistance may prevail ➑️ ⏩ πŸ’¬ The effectiveness of a trade union is significantly shaped by how organised and unified it is 🏭 It depends on the market structure and monopsony power In a monopsony, where one employer dominates, wages are below competitive levels ➑️ Trade unions can raise wages closer to the socially efficient level without causing job losses ➑️ But in a competitive market, union wage rises may lead to unemployment ➑️ ⏩ πŸ—οΈ The benefits of a trade union are clearer in monopsonistic markets πŸ“ˆ It depends on productivity growth If rising wages are matched by increased productivity, firms can absorb the cost ➑️ This can lead to win-win outcomes: higher wages, stable employment, and output ➑️ But if productivity remains flat, firms may reduce employment to control costs ➑️ ⏩ πŸ’Ό The impact of trade unions is more positive when they align with productivity improvements πŸ’Ό It depends on the state of the economy In a booming economy, firms are better able to afford union-negotiated wage increases ➑️ This may support higher living standards without harming jobs ➑️ But in a recession, wage hikes may lead to layoffs or reduced hours ➑️ ⏩ πŸ“‰ The macroeconomic context shapes whether trade union actions are sustainable or harmful 🌍 It depends on the industry In labour-intensive or low-margin industries, wage rises can hit profitability hard ➑️ Leading to relocation, outsourcing or redundancies ➑️ But in high-skill, high-profit sectors, unions may drive better outcomes without risk ➑️ ⏩ βš–οΈ Sector-specific factors determine how feasible or risky union demands are
32
macro disadvantages of trade unions
cost push inflation - Unions negotiate higher wages for workers, raising COL - Firms pass on these higher costs to consumers in the form of higher prices. - Increased prices can contribute to overall inflation in the economy. - Persistent inflation can erode purchasing power and slow down economic growth. - Unemployment: - Higher wages increase labor costs for firms, reducing their demand for labor. - Firms may lay off workers or reduce hiring to cut costs. - This can increase unemployment, particularly among low-skilled workers. - Higher unemployment may reduce aggregate demand, leading to slower economic growth. - Decreased Labor Market Flexibility: - Union contracts often include rigid rules on working hours, wages, and hiring practices. - This reduces the flexibility of businesses to adjust to changes in the market (e.g., economic downturns). - Lack of flexibility can make it harder for firms to cut costs or innovate. - Reduced flexibility can lead to slower economic growth and lower adaptability in the global economy.
33
macro advantages of trade unions
Increased Aggregate Demand: - higher wages for workers, increases their disposable income. - With more income, workers spend more on goods and services. - Increased consumer spending boosts aggregate demand in the economy. - Higher demand can lead to economic growth, increased production, and job creation. Reduced Income Inequality: - Unions help raise wages for lower- and middle-income workers. - This reduces wage disparities between high- and low-income earners. - Less income inequality can foster social stability and reduce poverty. - A more equitable income distribution may increase overall economic welfare. Increased Productivity: - By advocating for better working conditions, unions help improve worker health and safety. - Healthier workers are more productive and motivated. - Increased productivity contributes to economic growth without requiring more inputs. - This can lead to a more competitive economy
34
evaluation points for macroeconomic trade union impacts
- higher wages and aggregate demand depends on the state of the economy. If the economy is near full employment, increased demand could lead to inflation rather than growth. In a recession, higher demand may have a stronger positive impact. - Increased Productivity: depends on whether the higher wages and better conditions lead to increased motivation or result in complacency. Additionally, the industry type matters: some industries might benefit more from improved working conditions than others. - Wage-Push Inflation: depends on the elasticity of demand for the firm's product. If demand is inelastic, firms may pass costs on to consumers. If demand is elastic, firms may absorb the costs, limiting the inflationary impact. - Unemployment: Depends on: The elasticity of demand for labor. If demand for labor is inelastic, higher wages may not significantly reduce employment. However, in industries where labor demand is elastic, job losses could be more significant.
35
why might a trade union not work in a monopsonic market
Union-Set Wage May Be Below Competitive Wage: In a monopsony, wages are typically set below the competitive equilibrium because the firm has power over wage-setting. While the trade union can negotiate higher wages, they may not reach the market equilibrium wage, which is where supply and demand for labor would naturally meet in a competitive market. πŸ’” 1. Employer power may still dominate negotiations A monopsonist (e.g. NHS) may still have significant market power despite union presence ➑️ They can resist union demands due to lack of alternative employers for workers ➑️ Workers have low bargaining power if they can’t easily leave ➑️ ⏩ πŸ’Ό The union may struggle to influence wages or conditions effectively βš–οΈ 2. Government-imposed wage restraints In public sector monopsonies, the government may set strict wage controls or pay caps ➑️ Even if unions demand higher wages, the employer is restricted legally or fiscally ➑️ This limits the union’s ability to secure better deals ➑️ ⏩ 🧾 Union impact is weakened by external budgetary constraints πŸ§β€β™€οΈ 3. Low union membership weakens influence In some sectors, union density is very low, reducing collective bargaining power ➑️ Employers may feel under no pressure to negotiate ➑️ Individual workers lack influence and may fear retaliation for striking ➑️ ⏩ 🀐 Without strong membership, union efforts may be ignored πŸ“‰ 4. Risk of job losses or reduced hours If a union pushes for higher wages above MRP, the monopsonist may reduce employment ➑️ This can lead to job cuts, reduced hours, or hiring freezes ➑️ Particularly likely if demand for the firm’s output is falling ➑️ ⏩ ⚠️ Union action could backfire, harming the very workers it aims to protect
36
labour market failure
🚫 Discrimination πŸ”— Unfair treatment in hiring or promotion based on race, gender, or age can prevent qualified individuals from securing jobs πŸ”— This leads to underutilisation of talent and an inefficient allocation of labour πŸ”— As a result, some workers remain unemployed or underpaid, while employers miss out on skilled candidates πŸ”— Discrimination wastes valuable human capital and increases inequality in the labour market πŸ’”βš–οΈ πŸ“š Imperfect Information πŸ”— Workers may lack knowledge about job opportunities, wages, or the specific skills employers demand πŸ”— Similarly, employers may not know the full range of skills a potential employee has, leading to missed opportunities πŸ”— This information gap can lead to mismatches where workers take jobs that don't align with their qualifications, or employers hire workers who aren't the best fit πŸ”— The inefficient allocation of labour results in unemployment or underemployment πŸ“‰πŸ§  πŸ› οΈ Skills Shortages πŸ”— There may be a mismatch between the skills employers demand and the skills available in the workforce πŸ”— This leads to vacancies in certain sectors or industries, where employers can't find qualified workers πŸ”— On the other hand, some workers may be overqualified for the jobs available, leading to structural unemployment πŸ”— Skills shortages cause a labour market failure as some sectors face empty positions and others have surplus workers πŸ‘·β€β™€οΈπŸ” πŸšΆβ€β™€οΈ Labour Immobility πŸ”— Geographical or occupational immobility means workers may find it difficult to move to other locations or industries with more job opportunities πŸ”— This is often due to family ties, housing costs, or lack of transferable skills πŸ”— As a result, workers remain in areas or sectors with limited job prospects, while other areas face labour shortages πŸ”— Labour immobility creates inefficiency and prevents optimal allocation of workers across regions 🌍🏚️ 🏒 Monopsony Power πŸ”— A monopsony occurs when a single employer (or a few large employers) dominates the labour market in a particular area πŸ”— These employers can suppress wages and reduce the bargaining power of workers, leading to lower wages than would be expected in a competitive market πŸ”— Workers may also face limited job options and poor working conditions, as they have few alternative employers to turn to πŸ”— Monopsony power results in inefficiencies and wage suppression, harming both workers and the overall labour market πŸ“‰πŸ‘₯ πŸ’Έ Inequality πŸ”— Wide disparities in income and wealth can create disincentives to work, particularly for lower-income groups πŸ”— Workers may feel discouraged from entering or remaining in the workforce if they believe they won't earn a livable wage πŸ”— Income inequality can also lead to unequal access to education, training, and job opportunities, exacerbating labour market failure πŸ”— Inequality leads to a less productive workforce and a misallocation of resources πŸ’°βš–οΈ πŸ’΅ Tax and Welfare System πŸ”— High marginal tax rates or complex benefit systems can discourage individuals from entering or remaining in the workforce πŸ”— For example, workers may find that earning more results in higher taxes or a reduction in benefits, creating a disincentive to work πŸ”— This discourages some individuals from seeking higher-paying jobs or pursuing promotions πŸ”— The tax and welfare system creates inefficiencies in the labour market by distorting work incentives πŸ›οΈπŸ“‰ 🌍 Geographical Barriers πŸ”— Geographical barriers, such as high housing costs, limited transportation options, or regional unemployment, can prevent workers from seeking jobs in other areas πŸ”— These barriers create a mismatch between where workers are located and where the available jobs are, contributing to labour shortages in some areas and unemployment in others πŸ”— Workers may also face additional costs (such as moving expenses) that discourage them from relocating for better job opportunities πŸ”— Geographical barriers contribute to inefficiency in the labour market by limiting worker mobility 🌍πŸ