L2: Theoretical Tools of Public Finance Flashcards
how consumers make choices
represent preferences with a utility function
show how to represent preferences graphically
model budget constraints that individuals face
show how individuals maximise utility given their budget constraints
utility function
mathematical function which translates well-being from different consumption bundles into units that can be compared in order to determine choice
indifference curve
graphical representation of all bundles of goods that make an individual equally well off
2 key properties of indifference curves
consumers prefer higher indifference curves
- moving up from the origin as you increase consumption of either good
indifference curves are always downwards-sloping
- convexity
- tendency to not choose extreme versions of a basket between two goods
marginal utility
increment to utility obtained by consuming an additional unit of a good
marginal rate of substitution
rate at which the consumers will trade off the good on the vertical axis for that on the horizontal axis
slope of the indifference curve
budget constraint
mathematical representation of all combinations of goods one can buy using all income
fact that individuals have limited resources
substitution effect
holding utility constant, a relative rise in the price of a good will always cause an individual to choose less of that good
changing relative price but keeping the individual on the same indifference curve
income effect
rise in the price of a good will typically cause an individual to choose less of all goods because income can purchase less than before
changing income but not relative prices
normal goods
goods for which demand increases as income rises
inferior goods
goods for which demand decreases as income rises
elasticity of demand
% change in demand caused by a 1% change in price
typically negative, since demand falls as price rises
not constant along a demand curve but defined at a particular point
cross-price elasticity
how responsive demand for good 1 is to price of good 2
horizontal demand curve
perfectly elastic demand
vertical demand curve
perfectly inelastic demand
marginal cost
incremental cost to a firm of producing one more unit of a good
elasticity of supply
% change in supply for a 1% increase in price
social efficiency
net gains to society from all trades that are made in a market
sum of consumer and producer surplus
consumer surplus
benefit consumers derive from consuming a good, above and beyond the price they pay for the good
producer surplus
benefit producers derive from selling a good, above and beyond the cost of producing that good
first fundamental theorem of welfare economics
competitive equilibrium, where supply equals demand, maximises social efficiency
holds with no failures
results in pareto efficiency
deadweight loss
reduction in social efficiency from preventing trades for which benefits exceed costs
pareto efficiency
not possible to make someone better off without making someone else worse off
desirable but says nothing about how well-being is distributed
second fundamental theorem of welfare economics
any pareto efficient outcome can be reached by
- redistribution of initial endowments (individualised lump-sum taxes based on characteristics but not actual behaviour)
- letting markets work efficiently thereafter