2. Open Access Flashcards
Write down the sensible growth model
G(S) = aS (1 – S/K)
Reasons for surplus growth in the growth model?
- Fewer fish, more food available for each
- Fishing means fewer old, slow-growing fish (fishing target older and larger fish)
- Fewer old fish could mean less predation on young fish
If S < S_msy.
- Biological overexploitation
- But do not need to be economically overexploited
- Might be economically defensible
What is the simple “classical” fishery model?
Y=EqS
1. E = fishing effort. The activity of removing fish from the sea
2. One unit of effort removes a certain fraction of the fish stock (S)
3. Y = catch of fish
4. q = constant coefficient related to how we measure effort and stock (catchability, or availability coefficient)
Show a simple example of how biological overexploitation can be justified
- Surpluss growth function: G(S)=aS(1-S/K). Also, lets say that a 0.5, K=1, S_msy=0.5
- Draw graph. Overexploited to the left, underexploited to the right, fully exploited at S_msy in the middle.
- (a) G(0.5) = 0.5*0.5 * (1 - 0.5/1) = 0.125
- We now reduce the stock from 0.5 to 0.45. This gives an immediate gain by p=∆S=0.05, where p is the price of fish net cost
• 0.05 increase in captures
• But smaller stock is less productive - (b) G(0.45) = 0.5 * 0.45 * 0.55 = 0.12375
- Annual loss is (a)-(b) 0.125 – 0.12375 = 0.00125
- The present value of the loss in perpetuity is 0.00125/r. With 5% discount rate, we get 0.025
- 0.05 > 0.025 (with 5% discount rate). The value of the one-tme gain is bigger than the perpetuity loss
• Makes sense to take a smaller sustainable yield than the maximum.
Find sustainable stock level and sustainable yield as a function of effort
The logistic growth function:
(1) aS(1-S/K)
Catch of fish:
(2) Y=qES
Put (1) and (2) equal and we get the sustainable stock level as a function of effort:
(3) S_sus=K(1-Eq/a)
Insert this stock level into (2) and we get the sustainable yield as a function of effort:
(1) Y_sus = E – βE^2
= qK
β = q^2K/a
Find sustainable stock level and sustainable yield as a function of effort
The logistic growth function:
(1) aS(1-S/K)
Catch of fish:
(2) Y=qES
We set the catch of fish (2) equal to the growth of fish (1):
(3) aS(1-S/K) = qES
Solving for S, we get the sustainable fish stock level as a function of fishing effort:
(4) S_sus=K(1-Eq/a)
Next, we want to find the sustainable yield. We know that alpha and beta is:
(5) Β = q^2K/a
(6) = qk
Formula for Y_sus (sustainable yield) is now:
(7) Y_sus=qEK(1-Eq/a)
Insert this stock level into (2) and we get the sustainable yield as a function of effort:
(7) Y_sus = E – βE^2
= qK
β = q^2K/a
What are the assumptions?
- Constant cost per unit of effort
* Some fishermen are more clever than other, or have better equipment and earn profits (skill or equipment rents)
* Implies a rising curve of cost per unit of effort
* The marginal fisherman still breaks even (unit cost = average product > marginal product), but we still have overexplotation under open access) - Quantity-dependent price of fish, p=f(Y)
* The sustainable yield curve can have two peaks, and we can get three equilibria with open access, but there will still be overexploitation (MP < c) - A different production function, such as
Y = ES^b
0 ≤ b ≤ 1
q = 1
- b < 1 could be due to how fish change their distribution in the sea as the stock dimishes. Open access would still result in overexploitation and possibly extinction
- Catch per unit of effort: Y/E = ES^b/E = S^b
- If b < 1, Y/E falls less quickly than the stock
- If b = 0, fish stocks would go extinct under open access, pY/E > c always and there is always an incentive to expand fishing effort
- For demersal fish, b probably close to 1, for pelagic fish which move in shoals (herring, mackerel, etc., close to 0).
What are the consequences of open access?
- Leads to economic overexploitation
- Leads to extinction of fish stocks if cost per unit of fish caught is independent of stock size (think buffalo)
a) So fishermen have incentive to max short-term, neglecting long-term
When do we have biological overexploitation?
When the fish stock is S < S_msy
Q: What is the relation between biological and economical overexploitation?
a) economic overexploitation typically means biological overexploitation
b) but biological overexploitation does not necessarily mean economical overexploitation (can be justified)
Can biological overexploitation be justified?
Can be justified economically, if the cost per unit of fish caught is insensitive to the stock size. (some loss of future sustainable yield can be traded off against unsustainable gain)
a) cost per unit of gain is INSENSITIVE to stock size. Expenses remain constant
Q: Explain the difference between a open-access fishery and a regulated fishery (text)
Open-access:
* Available to all (who, how much, when).
* Act in self-interest, and behave contrary to the common good by depleting the shared resource.
Open, economically
* Continue to fish as long revenue > cost.
* May lead to NOT sustainable level, both biologically and economically
* Effort could be greater than sustainable yield, which could lead to overfishing
Regulated:
* Rules and regulations
* Limits on allowable catch, restrictions on gear or techniques, limitations on fishing season
* Aim: Sustainability and NOT deplete fish stocks
Regulated, economically:
* Aim is to achieve maximum sustainable yield (highest yield that can be sustainably fished from the stock year after year)
* This level is achieved by controlling the fishing effort such that the marginal productivity, the value contributed by the last unit of effort, is equal to the cost per unit of effort.
* Prevents overexploitation of the fish stock and ensures that the fishing activities are economically sustainable.
Q: Explain the difference between a open-access fishery and a regulated fishery (show graphs)
Open Access Explanation:
* Individuals self-interest
Figure 4.3 Upper Panel:
* Sustainable yield: represents the amount of fish that can be harvested sustainably at different levels of effort
* Cost lines: indicate the total cost incurred for different fishing efforts
* E1^* and E2^*: represent open-access equilibria, where the total revenues from the fishing match the total costs
You can see that, paradoxically, lower costs lead to more fishing effort and less sustainable yield, indicative of overfishing in an open-access scenario. The lower panel of Figure 4.3 helps clarify this.
* The downward-sloping AP (Average Productivity) and MP (Marginal Productivity) lines reflect the diminishing returns in fishing productivity with increasing fishing effort.
* Under open-access conditions, equilibrium occurs when AP equals the cost per unit of effort (at points E1^* and E2^*), meaning the last unit of effort is not paying for itself—it contributes less to the total value than it costs.
Regulated Fishery:
Figure 4.3 Upper Panel:
* The points E1^0 and E2^0 represent the economically optimal level of fishing effort, where the marginal productivity line intersects with the cost per unit of effort line.
* This implies less effort than under open access, and the effort would not exceed the effort producing the maximum sustainable yield.
Figure 4.3 Lower Panel:
* The optimal effort levels E1^0 and E2^0 occur when the Marginal Productivity (MP) equals the cost per unit of effort.
* Here, each unit of effort or boat contributes a net value to the fishery equal to its cost, maximizing the difference between revenues and costs—known as the resource rent or fishing rent.
what is effort?
Can be a lot and can be measured in different ways:
1. Hours of trawling
2. Size of boats
3. Number of hooks applies
4. Etc.