The Labour Market Flashcards
What is derived demand?
Derived demand refers to the demand for a factor of production (such as labour, capital, or raw materials) that arises from the demand for the final goods and services it helps produce. In other words, it is not demanded for its own sake but because it contributes to the production of something that consumers want.
Example: bricklayers and houses are derived demand
What does marginal productivity theory of labour demand states?
This theory states that a firm’s demand for labour depends on the marginal revenue product of labour (MRP), which is calculated as:
MRP = MPP x price (MR)
Where:
• MPP (Marginal Physical Product) = the additional output produced by an extra worker
• MR (Marginal Revenue) = the additional revenue gained from selling this extra output
A profit-maximising firm will hire workers until MRP = wage rate. If MRP exceeds the wage, hiring more workers is profitable. If MRP is lower than the wage, the firm will reduce employment.
What does labour demand curve show?
The labour demand curve shows the relationship between the wage rate and the quantity of labour employed. It is generally downward sloping, meaning that:
• At higher wages, firms demand less labour because hiring workers becomes more expensive. • At lower wages, firms demand more labour, as the cost of employing workers is lower.
What factors can causes the shifts of the labour demand curve?
- Changes in Product Demand
If demand for the final product increases, firms need more workers to produce more goods, shifting labour demand right.
If product demand falls, labour demand shifts left. - Labour Productivity
Higher worker productivity (more output per worker) increases MRP, shifting the demand curve right.
Lower productivity shifts labour demand left. - Price of Capital (Substitutes and Complements)
If capital (e.g., robots, machines) becomes cheaper and replaces labour, demand for labour falls (left shift).
If labour and capital are complements (e.g., workers needed to operate new machines), cheaper capital may increase labour demand (right shift). - Changes in the Cost of Other Factors of Production
If raw materials become expensive, firms may cut production, reducing the demand for labour (left shift).
If energy costs fall, firms may expand production, increasing labour demand (right shift). - Technology
Automation can reduce the demand for certain jobs (left shift).
Technological advancements in industries that require human oversight can increase demand for skilled labour (right shift).- Government Policies & Regulations
• Higher employment taxes or stricter labour laws (e.g., minimum wages, union regulations) increase costs, shifting labour demand left.
• Subsidies for hiring workers (e.g., apprenticeship incentives) can shift labour demand right.
- Government Policies & Regulations
What the determinants of the elasticity of demand for labour?
- Labour Substitutability
If workers can easily be replaced by machines or other inputs, demand for labour is elastic (e.g., factory workers).
If workers are difficult to replace (e.g., highly skilled professionals), demand is inelastic. - Labour’s Share of Total Costs
If labour costs form a large proportion of total costs (e.g., hospitality sector), firms are more sensitive to wage changes, making demand elastic.
If labour costs are a small proportion (e.g., capital-intensive industries), demand is inelastic. - Price Elasticity of Demand for the Final Product
If the final product has elastic demand (luxury goods), firms are more sensitive to labour cost changes, making labour demand more elastic.
If the product has inelastic demand (necessities), firms can pass on wage increases to consumers, making labour demand inelastic. - Time Period
In the short run, labour demand is more inelastic because firms cannot easily adjust workforce sizes.
In the long run, firms can invest in automation or restructure, making demand more elastic.
What monetary factors to affect the supply of labour?
Wage rate – Higher wages attract more workers, increasing labour supply.
Bonuses and overtime pay – Extra financial incentives encourage more people to enter a profession.
Pensions and benefits – Good retirement plans, healthcare, or insurance can make a job more attractive.
Tips - Some services jobs may get tips from customers.
What non monetary factors that may affect the supply of labour?
Job satisfaction – Enjoyable and meaningful work can increase labour supply even if wages are lower.
Working conditions – Safe, comfortable, and flexible work environments attract more workers.
Work-life balance – Jobs with flexible hours or remote work may encourage more people to join.
Career progression – Opportunities for promotion and skill development increase the attractiveness of an occupation.
Job risk and stress – Dangerous or highly stressful jobs (e.g., firefighters, air traffic controllers) may have a lower labour supply unless wages are significantly high.
What is labour supply curve? What does it show?
The labour supply curve shows the relationship between the wage rate and the number of workers willing to work in an occupation.
It generally slopes upward, meaning that higher wages attract more workers.
However, at very high wage levels, workers may prefer leisure over work, leading to a backward-bending supply curve.
What factors could causes the shifts of labour supply curve?
- Changes in Working Population
An increase in immigration or a growing working-age population shifts supply right.
An ageing population or decline in birth rates shifts supply left. - Education and Training
Improved education and training increase the number of qualified workers, shifting supply right.
A lack of training opportunities reduces supply, shifting it left. - Wages in Alternative Occupations
If wages rise in alternative jobs, workers may switch, reducing supply (left shift).
If alternative job wages fall, more workers stay, increasing supply (right shift). - Non-Wage Benefits
Better working conditions, flexible hours, or strong career growth shift labour supply right. - Barriers to Entry
High qualifications or strict licensing reduce supply (left shift).
Reduced entry barriers (e.g., removing degree requirements) increase supply (right shift). - Social and Cultural Factors
Changing attitudes towards work (e.g., more women joining the workforce) shift supply right.
Social norms discouraging certain jobs (e.g., stigma around manual labour) shift supply left. - Government Policies
Lower income tax or increased childcare support can increase labour supply (right shift).
Higher income tax or strict employment laws can discourage work (left shift).
What is the economist’s model of wage determination in a perfect competitive labour market?
In a perfectly competitive labour market, wages are determined by the interaction of labour demand and labour supply. The key assumptions of this model include:
Many employers and many workers, none of whom can influence the wage rate.
Homogeneous labour (all workers have the same skills and productivity).
Perfect information (both employers and workers know all available job opportunities and wages).
No barriers to entry or exit in the labour market.
What effects of market changes on wage determination?
- Increase in Labour Demand (Shift Right in DL)
Causes: Higher product demand, improved worker productivity, or new technology complementing labour.
Effect: Higher wages and more employment. - Increase in Labour Supply (Shift Right in SL)
Causes: More immigration, better education, or social changes increasing workforce participation.
Effect: Lower wages but more employment. - Decrease in Labour Demand (Shift Left in DL)
Causes: Recession, automation replacing workers, or falling product demand.
Effect: Lower wages and fewer jobs. - Decrease in Labour Supply (Shift Left in SL)
Causes: Ageing population, reduced migration, or strict licensing laws.
Effect: Higher wages but fewer workers available.
What is the role of market forces (supply and demand) in determining relative wage rates?
- Skill Levels and Training Requirements
Highly skilled jobs (e.g., doctors, engineers) have lower supply due to long training periods, leading to higher wages.
Low-skilled jobs (e.g., retail workers) have higher supply, leading to lower wages. - Labour Productivity
More productive workers contribute more to a firm’s revenue (higher MRP), increasing demand for their labour and raising wages. - Compensating Wage Differentials
Dangerous, unpleasant, or stressful jobs (e.g., oil rig workers, night shift jobs) must offer higher wages to attract workers. - Barriers to Entry
Occupations with high qualifications, licensing, or union restrictions (e.g., doctors, pilots) have limited supply, leading to higher wages. - Union Influence
Strong labour unions can negotiate higher wages (e.g., for teachers or airline pilots), while non-unionised jobs may have lower wages. - Gender and Discrimination
Wage differentials can exist due to gender gaps, ethnicity, or historical discrimination, though many policies aim to reduce these differences. - Geographical Immobility
If workers are unwilling or unable to move to high-wage areas (e.g., due to housing costs or family ties), regional wage differences persist.
How does monopsony power contribute to imperfections in a labour market?
A monopsony is a market where there is only one dominant employer (or very few employers), giving them significant control over wages and employment levels.
How Monopsony Causes Labour Market Imperfections:
Employers can pay wages lower than the competitive equilibrium wage since workers have limited alternative job options.
Employment levels tend to be lower than in a perfectly competitive labour market.
Workers may lack bargaining power due to the lack of competing employers.
Examples of Monopsony Power:
The NHS in the UK, which is the largest employer of doctors and nurses.
Gig economy platforms like Uber, where workers have limited power to negotiate wages.
How do trade unions contribute to imperfections in a labour market?
Trade unions are worker organisations that collectively bargain for better wages, working conditions, and benefits.
How Trade Unions Cause Labour Market Imperfections:
Higher wages above equilibrium – Unions may negotiate wages above the market rate, potentially leading to unemployment if firms hire fewer workers.
Restricted labour supply – Some unions limit membership, creating barriers to entry in certain professions (e.g., electricians, plumbers).
Labour market rigidities – Strong unions may resist necessary workplace changes or automation, reducing market efficiency.
Examples of Union Influence:
The RMT (Rail, Maritime and Transport) union in the UK, which negotiates pay for railway workers.
The British Medical Association (BMA), representing doctors in wage disputes
How does imperfect information contributes to imperfections in a labour market?
Workers and employers often lack full information about wages, job opportunities, or working conditions, leading to inefficiencies.
How Imperfect Information Causes Labour Market Imperfections:
Workers may accept lower wages than they deserve because they are unaware of better-paying jobs.
Employers may struggle to find suitable workers, leading to skills mismatches and inefficient employment.
Delays in job mobility – Workers might remain in low-paid jobs due to uncertainty about new opportunities.
Examples of Imperfect Information:
Graduates may not know the full salary range for their field and accept lower wages.
Job seekers may not be aware of vacancies in other cities due to poor access to job postings.
What other factors contributing to labour market imperfections?
- Geographical Immobility – Workers may be unwilling or unable to move for better jobs due to housing costs or family commitments.
- Discrimination – Wage disparities may exist due to gender, race, or other biases.
- Government Regulations – Minimum wage laws, employment protections, and migration policies can distort market forces.
How the employer in monopsony labour market can use market power to reduce both the relative wage rate and the level of employment below those that would exist in a perfectly competitive labour market?
In a monopsony labour market, a single dominant employer has significant market power, allowing them to set wages and employment levels rather than taking them as given. Unlike in a perfectly competitive labour market, where firms hire workers until the marginal revenue product of labour (MRP) equals the wage rate, a monopsonist faces an upward-sloping labour supply curve, meaning they must offer higher wages to attract additional workers. However, because hiring more workers raises the marginal cost of labour (MCL) faster than the wage rate, the monopsonist maximises profits by employing labour at the point where MCL = MRP, rather than where labour supply meets MRP as in perfect competition. As a result, both wages (Wm) and employment levels (Qm) are lower than in a competitive market. This leads to the exploitation of workers, as they are paid less than their true productivity, and creates inefficiency, as some workers who would be willing to work at a higher competitive wage (W*) are left unemployed.
What are the various factors that affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and levels of employment in different labour markets?
Trade unions’ ability to influence wages and employment varies based on labour demand elasticity, market conditions, union density, legal environment, and employer strength.
In monopsony markets or skilled labour industries, unions can effectively raise wages with minimal job losses. However, in highly competitive, low-skilled, or anti-union environments, their influence is limited.
How does the elasticity of demand for labour affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
If the demand for labour is inelastic, unions can negotiate higher wages without significantly reducing employment (e.g., healthcare, where workers are essential).
If demand is elastic, wage increases may lead to substantial job losses as firms cut costs or automate (e.g., manufacturing).
How does market structure and employer power affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
Monopsony Employers: Unions can be more effective in raising wages in monopsony markets, where employers exploit workers by setting low wages.
Competitive Labour Markets: In markets with many employers, unions may struggle as workers have alternative job options.
How does union membership and density affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
Higher union density (a larger proportion of workers in the union) strengthens bargaining power, increasing the likelihood of wage increases.
Declining membership reduces union influence, as seen in industries like retail and hospitality.
How does the strength of union legislation affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
In countries with strong labour laws, such as France and Germany, unions have more legal support for collective bargaining and striking.
In countries with anti-union policies (e.g., restrictive strike laws in the UK), unions have less power.
How does substitutability of labour affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
If skilled workers are difficult to replace, unions have more power (e.g., pilots, doctors).
If workers are easily replaceable, employers can resist union demands by hiring non-union workers.
How does the financial strength of employers affect the ability of trade unions to influence wages and employment?
Large, profitable firms are more likely to afford union wage demands.
Firms under financial pressure may resist wage increases or relocate jobs to cheaper regions.