Chapter 9: Basic Oligopoly Models Flashcards
Oligopoly
A market structure in which there are only a few firms, each of which is large relative to the total industry.
Relatively few large firms in an industry. But no explicit number of firms is required for oligopoly, but the number usually is somewhere between 2 and 10.
The products the firms offer may be either identical (as in a perfectly competitive market) or differentiated (as in a monopolistically competitive market).
An oligopoly composed of only two firms is called a duopoly.
Oligopoly Interdependence
The actions of other firms will have a profound impact on the manager’s optimal decisions.
Example: Several firms selling differentiated products compete in an oligopoly. In determining what price to charge, the manager must consider the impact of his or her decisions on other firms in the industry.
If the price for the product is lowered, will other firms lower their prices or maintain their existing prices? If the price is increased, will other firms do likewise or maintain their current prices?
The optimal decision of whether to raise or lower price will depend on how the manager believes other managers will respond.
If other firms lower their prices when the firm lowers its price, it will not sell as much as it would if the other firms maintained their existing prices.
Oligopoly Demand Curve
Demand Depends on Actions of Rivals.
Suppose the firm initially is at point B, charging a price of P0.
Demand curve D1 is based on the assumption that rivals will match any price change, while D2 is based on the assumption that they will not match a price change.
Is demand more or less elastic when rivals match a price change?
Demand is less elastic and more inelastic when rivals match a price change than when they do not.
For a given price reduction, a firm will sell more if rivals do not cut their prices (D2) than it will if they lower their prices (D1). In effect, a price reduction increases quantity demanded only slightly when rivals respond by lowering their prices. Similarly, for a given price increase, a firm will sell more when rivals also raise their prices (D1) than it will when they maintain their existing prices (D2).
Matching Pricing Decisions between Firms
The demand for a firm’s product in oligopoly depends critically on how rivals respond to the firm’s pricing decisions.
If rivals will match any price change, the demand curve for the firm’s product is given by D1. In this instance, the manager will maximize profits where the marginal revenue associated with demand curve D1 equals marginal cost.
If rivals will not match any price change, the demand curve for the firm’s product is given by D2. In this instance, the manager will maximize profits where the marginal revenue associated with demand curve D2 equals marginal cost. In each case, the profit- maximizing rule is the same as that under monopoly; the only difficulty for the firm manager is determining whether or not rivals will match price changes.
Profit Maximization in Three Oligopoly Settings
Profit maximization differs based on alternative assumptions regarding how rivals will respond to price or output changes.
Each of the three models has different implications for the manager’s optimal decisions, and these differences arise because of differences in the ways rivals respond to the firm’s actions.
Cournot Oligopoly
An industry in which
(1) there are few firms in the market serving many consumers, (2) firms produce either differentiated or homogeneous (identical) products, (3) each firm believes rivals will hold their output constant if it changes its output, and (4) barriers to entry exist.
The Cournot model is relevant for decision making when managers make output decisions and believe that their decisions do not affect the output decisions of rival firms.
Firm 2 is the “mirror image” of firm 1.
Cournot Oligopoly Example
A few large oil producers must decide how much oil to pump out of the ground. The total amount of oil produced will certainly affect the market price of oil, but the underly- ing decision of each firm is not a pricing decision but rather the quantity of oil to produce. If each firm must determine its output level at the same time other firms determine their output levels, or, more generally, if each firm expects its own output decision to have no impact on rivals’ output decisions, then this scenario describes a Cournot oligopoly.
Reaction Function
A best-response function (also called a reaction function) defines the profit-maximizing level of output for a firm for given output levels of another firm.
Reaction Function: Example
Suppose there are only two firms competing in a Cournot duopoly: Each firm must make an output decision, and each firm believes that its rival will hold output constant as it changes its own output.
To determine its optimal output level, firm 1 will equate marginal revenue with marginal cost. Notice that since this is a duopoly, firm 1’s marginal revenue is affected by firm 2’s output level. In particular, the greater the output of firm 2, the lower the market price and thus the lower is firm 1’s marginal revenue.
The profit-maximizing level of output for firm 1 depends on firm 2’s output level: A greater output by firm 2 leads to a lower profit-maximizing output for firm 1. This relationship between firm 1’s profit-maximizing output and firm 2’s output is called a best-response or reaction function.
More formally, the profit- maximizing level of output for firm 1 given that firm 2 produces Q2 units of output is
Q1 = r1(Q2)
Similarly, the profit-maximizing level of output for firm 2 given that firm 1 produces Q1 units
of output is given by
Q2 = r2(Q1)
Cournot Reaction Functions for a Duopoly: Graph
Firm 1’s output is measured on the horizontal axis and firm 2’s output is measured on the vertical axis.
Profit Maximizing Response by Firm 1
If firm 2 produced zero units of output, the profit- maximizing level of output for firm 1 would be Q1M since this is the point on firm 1’s reaction function (r1) that corresponds to zero units of Q2.
This combination of outputs corresponds to the situation where only firm 1 is producing a positive level of output; thus, Q1M corresponds to the situation where firm 1 is a monopolist.
If instead of producing zero units of output firm 2 produced Q2 units, the profit-maximizing level of output for firm 1 would be Q1 since this is the point on r1 that corresponds to an output of Q*2 by firm 2.
The reason the profit-maximizing level of output for firm 1 decreases as firm 2’s output increases is: The demand for firm 1’s product depends on the output produced by other firms in the market. When firm 2 increases its level of output, the demand and marginal revenue for firm 1 decline. The profit-maximizing response by firm 1 is to reduce its level of output.
Cournot Equilibrium
A situation in which neither firm has an incentive to change its output given the other firm’s output.
Cournot Equilibrium: Example
Suppose firm 1 produces Q1M units of output.
Given this output, the profit-maximizing level of output for firm 2 will correspond to point A on r2 in Figure 9–3.
Given this positive level of output by firm 2, the profit-maximizing level of output for firm 1 will no longer be Q1M, but will correspond to point B on r1.
Given this reduced level of output by firm 1, point C will be the point on firm 2’s reaction function that maximizes profits. Given this new output by firm 2, firm 1 will again reduce output to point D on its reaction function.
Changes in output continue until point E is reached. At point E, firm 1 produces Q1 and firm 2 produces Q2 units.
Neither firm has an incentive to change its output given that it believes the other firm will hold its output constant at that level.
Point E thus corresponds to the Cournot equilibrium.
Cournot equilibrium is the situation where neither firm has an incentive to change its output given the output of the other firm. Graphically, this condition corresponds to the intersection of the reaction curves.
Solving for the Cournot equilibrium
To maximize profits, a manager in a Cournot oligopoly produces where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
The calculation of marginal cost is straightforward; it is done just as in the other market structures we have analyzed. The calculation of marginal revenues is a little more subtle.