Chapter 2 Flashcards
Frédéric Bastiat
(Pro-Libre-échange)
Frédéric Bastiat was a French economist, writer, and member of the French National Assembly. He was a proponent of classical liberal economic policies and free trade, and is known for his essays and books advocating for these ideas.
One of his most famous works is “Harmonies économiques” (Economic Harmonies), which was published in 1850. In this work, Bastiat argues that free trade and economic cooperation among nations leads to greater prosperity and peace. He also criticizes government intervention in the economy, arguing that it leads to unintended consequences and undermines individual freedom.
“Harmonies économiques” is considered a classic of free-market economic thought and continues to be influential today among advocates of free trade and limited government intervention in the economy.
What are some origins/authors of libre-echange?
The historical origins of the idea of free trade, can be traced back to philosophers such as John Locke, David Hume, and Adam Smith, who advocated for the opening of borders to ideas and commerce. In France, authors such as J. Turgot, Condillac, F. Bastiat, and Ch. L. Montesquieu argued against state intervention in commerce, asserting that the state’s only legitimate role is to protect individual liberties.
Charles de Montesquieu
(Pro Libre-Echange)
- Montesquieu is most well-known for his book “The Spirit of Laws,” which was published in 1748. “De l’esprit des lois”
- Montesquieu was also a proponent of individual liberty and freedom of thought. He believed that the state had a responsibility to protect the individual rights of its citizens, and that people should have the freedom to express their opinions and beliefs without fear of persecution.
- Charles de Montesquieu argued in favor of the freedom of trade and commerce as a condition for peace between nations.
- He believed that commerce could cure destructive prejudices and promote gentle manners.
- He also argued that the natural effect of commerce is to lead to peace, as two nations that trade together become mutually dependent on each other.
- Montesquieu saw the word “negotiation” (negotium in Latin) as synonymous with the negation of idleness and inactivity, suggesting that commerce promotes dynamism and economic growth
Plaidoyers plus récents pour le libre-échange
Yagdish Bhagwati
Paul Samuelson
Yagdish Bhagwati
Yagdish Bhagwati argues that free trade not only promotes global economic development but also that opposing it will not better protect social rights and the environment. He believes that protectionist tendencies, particularly in the anti-globalization movement, harm not only the countries that adopt them but also others.
Paul Samuelson
Paul Samuelson argues that free trade creates a surplus of global wealth that can be shared. He notes that economists unanimously support free trade, even those who have sought to refine traditional theories of international trade. Even poor countries, with lower productivity than rich countries, have an interest in liberalizing trade. However, Samuelson notes that politicians are often opposed to free trade, setting up a unique divide between economists and policymakers.
Argument of Pascal Lamy
Pascal Lamy, a practitioner’s point of view, argues that commerce creates a continuity between underdevelopment and development, as evidenced by the increasing production of developing countries surpassing that of developed countries. He acknowledges that globalization has lifted billions of people out of poverty but also resulted in growing inequalities. Lamy believes that protectionism and economic patriotism are no longer relevant and points out that the proportion of imported components in exported products has increased from 20% to 40%, and will continue to rise, making the idea of consuming and exporting only national products obsolete.
Arguments J.B Colbert and Maurice Allais
(Anti-Libre échange)
“Trade is a war of money” and “commerce is another way of waging war”
The economic system of Colbertism is based on the principles of mercantilism, whose objective is to allow the state to assert its rank.
The mercantilist doctrine justifies prohibitive practices, including the ban on imports of foreign finished products.
Globalization penalizes rich countries
Competition between unequal countries can be negative for developed countries, due to differences in wage levels and social protection.
Dani Rodrik
Anti- Libre échange
In “What do Trade Agreements Really do,” Dani Rodrik argues that the benefits of free trade are exaggerated. The idea of comparative advantage assumes that all countries play by the same rules, which is no longer the case. Liberalizing trade is also supposed to stimulate exports and create wealth and jobs, but only some countries are successful in doing so, leading to winners and losers. Trade agreements may create jobs in some countries but destroy them in others. Overall, free trade is only efficient if trade grows significantly and evenly, which is a challenging assumption in reality.
Samir Amin
Anti- Libre échange
Samir Amin argues that colonialism and capitalism are fundamentally inseparable, and that free trade is used as an instrument to exploit and pillage developing nations.
He characterizes the World Trade Organization (WTO) as a club of multinational corporations for the pillage of the third world, which protects the industrial and intellectual property rights of imperialist capitalist countries while establishing a false symmetry in market access that allows the exploitation of southern resources without giving these countries access to northern markets.
Amin calls this a global apartheid and a continuation of the colonial system.
Dix thèse favorable à la libéralisation des échanges
L.A.B.C.C.E.M.P.G.
“Labc-cem-pig”
Le libre échange accroît l’efficacité de la production
Le libre échange améliore le bien être
Le libre échange bénéficie aux consommateurs
Le libre échange corrige les inégalités internationales
Le libre échange égalise les conditions de développement
Le libre échange favorise la modernisation du pays entier
Le libre échange sert l’intérêt général
Le libre échange assure la paix sociale
Le libre échange garantit une meilleure protection de l’environnement
Le libre échange est la politique commerciale la moins risquée
Le libre échange accroît l’efficacité de la production
free trade leads to an increase in production efficiency. It encourages each country to specialize in the industries in which they are relatively more productive and abandon those in which they are less efficient. As a result, there is a more efficient allocation of resources, leading to greater overall economic efficiency. (Comparative Advantage)
Comparative Advantage
Comparative advantage is a concept in economics that describes the ability of a country, company, or individual to produce a particular good or service at a lower opportunity cost than others. It means that a country should specialize in producing the goods or services it can produce at a lower opportunity cost, and trade with other countries for goods or services that they can produce at a lower opportunity cost. This allows for increased efficiency and production, and overall economic benefits for all parties involved
Le libre échange améliore le bien être
free trade improves well-being by supporting economic growth and generating distributable surplus wealth. This is achieved through a mechanism whereby more trade leads to more division of labor, increased productivity, greater growth, more jobs, and higher incomes in the countries that engage in free trade.
Le libre échange soutient la croissance, et permet de dégager un surplus de richesses distribuables (gain from trade)
Le libre échange accroît le bien être dans les pays qui s’y engagent en vertu du mécanisme: plus de commerce -> plus de division du travail -> plus d’efficacité productive -> plus de croissance -> plus d’emplois et de revenus
Le libre échange bénéficie aux consommateurs
The free trade benefits consumers by increasing competition, leading to a greater variety and quality of goods available at lower prices. While it may harm certain businesses and sectors, these losses are generally offset by gains in other sectors and for consumers
Maquiladoras in Mexico
Maquiladoras are factories in Mexico that produce goods for export to the United States and other countries. They operate under a special program that allows them to import raw materials and equipment duty-free as long as the finished products are exported. The program was established in the 1960s as a way to promote economic development in Mexico and create jobs for its growing population.
Maquiladoras have been successful in creating jobs and generating income for Mexico, particularly in the border regions where they are concentrated. They have also been criticized for their low wages, poor working conditions, and environmental pollution.
However, from the perspective of the benefits to consumers, the Maquiladoras offer a good example of how free trade can benefit consumers. By allowing companies to move production to areas where labor and other costs are lower, free trade can result in lower prices for consumers. In the case of the Maquiladoras, they are able to produce goods at a lower cost than in the United States, and these cost savings are passed on to American consumers who purchase the finished products. This is one way in which free trade can benefit not only the producers but also the consumers who purchase their products.
Le libre échange corrige les inégalités internationales
The principle of free trade corrects international inequalities. The distribution of gains tends to favor the poorer countries, while the richer ones receive a smaller gain due to their higher demand which increases the price of imported goods. The free trade principle is thus effective and has corrective effects.
Paradoxe de J Stuart Mill
The “paradoxe de J Stuart Mill” refers to the observation made by the 19th century economist John Stuart Mill that the gains from trade tend to benefit the poorer nations more than the wealthier ones. This is paradoxical because one would expect that the wealthier nations, with their greater resources and more advanced technologies, would be the ones to benefit the most from trade. However, Mill argued that the opposite was true, since the wealthier nations tended to have a greater demand for imported goods, which drove up their prices and reduced the gains from trade.