Pay-for-Preformance Flashcards
Six Institute of Medicine Quality Aims
Care that is
- Effective: (based on evidence) - archives a good outcome
- Safe: decided of harm
- Timely: when patients need it
- Efficient: without waste for the delivery system or patient
- Patient-centered: respecting the preferences, culture, and circumstances of the patient and family
- Equitable: no inequity, difference or disparities in health outcomes that are systematic, avoidable or unjust
*Quality is not the best metric when evaluating a health system because it needs to be broken down
Case Payment Incentives
Positive Incentives: efficiency, gathering data, standardising care
- Incentivises increased activity overall
- Removes economic incentive to over-provide services for a single patient
- Easy to operate
Negative Incentives:
- Possible DRG-creep
- Cost shifting
- Cream skimping
- Increases unnecessary admissions (increases costs) and readmissions (decreases quality)
- Quality skimping
- Data fraud
- Low payment may lead to slow adoption of useful technology
4 Models of Public Service Delivery
Trust:
- The government sets the budget. Front-line professionals (physicians, managers, teachers…, etc.) decide how it is spent.
- Professionals allocate resources and submit bills to third-party payers (government, insurance companies)
Mistrust:
- We do not trust the provider to deliver appropriate care, so we have to incorporate some form of incentive or sanction and monitor their performance.
- It is based on performance measurements and some form of incentive or sanction or based on a high degree of control
Types
1. Managed care (US): insurers are exercising control over the provider’s sector by only contracting with certain of them or integrating directly with providers
2. Targets (UK): since already an integrated system in terms of the majority of hospital provision
3. P4P
4. Command and Control: Managerial Hierarchy
Mistrust will only work if:
- Government has the ‘right’ aims (and can pick the ‘right’ targets)
- The government knows the provider’s motivation, can monitor provider activities accurately and can devise an appropriate incentive structure
- Few opportunities for gaming
- Incentive structure does not drive out intrinsic (knightly) motivation
- Reporting requirements are manageable
Voice: giving patients a voice on how clinical care is provided to them, incorporating patients’ viewpoints in decision-making
Mechanisms:
- Informal face-to-face talks
- Board membership
- Consultative fora
- Complaints procedures
- Petitions
- Elected representatives
Choice of provider: at the heart of market reforms, giving patients a choice between providers such that they can vote with their feet in terms of who’s providing quality or care
- Providers are independent. Non-profit or for-profit. Keep any surplus they make on their budget
- Users choose provider. Money follows the choice. So hospitals etc get more resources through the number of users (patients) they attract.
Why include P4P
Current healthcare payment methods don’t incentivise quality care.
- Traditional methods focus on quantity: Payment methods like salary, fee-for-service, and capitation reward doctors for the number of patients they see, not necessarily the quality of care provided.
- Fee-for-service: Doctors get paid per service, regardless of its effectiveness in improving the patient’s health.
- Capitation: Doctors receive a set fee per patient enrolled, but patients are left to judge quality, which might not be reliable.
- Hospital payments (DRGs): While they consider the complexity of a patient’s case, they don’t directly measure the quality of care delivered.
In essence, the current system doesn’t financially reward doctors for improving patient health outcomes.
What is P4P
Performance-related pay means that payment is directly linked to the performance of providers.
Main idea: Linking payment to performance measures
Foundations: Existing payment mechanisms do not reward providers for higher-quality
Rooted in mistrust model
Theoretical basis: agency theory, microeconomic theory, and cognitive psychology
P4P refers to financial incentives for healthcare providers (supply-side).
Incentives are based on quality of care, not just delivering more services.
Arguments for P4P
- Can reward good effort and capability
- Forces payers to evaluate their payees
- Motivates people to perform better
Agency Theory
Principal (payer) —- Agent (doctor) —-Principal (Patient)
effort unobserved quality unobserved
- The problem with the principal-agent relationship in healthcare, is that firstly the payer cannot directly observe the effort of the doctor
- Patients cannot observe the quality of the care given by the doctor because of information asymmetry
Cognitive Psychology
Intrinsic motivationrefers to behaviour that is driven by internal rewards. In other words, themotivationto engage in a behaviour arises from within the individual because it is naturally satisfying to you.
Extrinsic motivationrefers to behaviour that is driven byexternalrewards such as money, fame, grades, and praise.
P4P Challenges
- Information asymmetry: Patients lack medical expertise to judge doctors’ recommendations.
- Medical uncertainty: Even doctors can’t predict the best course of treatment for every patient.
- Principal-agent problem: Patients (principals) rely on doctors (agents) to act in their best interest, but misaligned incentives can occur.
- Multiple agent problem: Adding a third-party payer (insurance company/government) creates conflicting goals between all parties.
P4P vs FFS and third-party payer
Traditional fee-for-service model incentives over treatment:
- Doctors are paid per service, leading to unnecessary procedures.
- Patients often lack the knowledge or power to question these practices.
- This model can lead to cost explosions, as seen in China.
Third-party payers face rising costs due to misaligned incentives:
- Patients with minimal cost burdens tend to overuse services when doctors recommend them.
- Payers need to control costs but lack control over utilisation.
P4P aims to address these issues by:
- Measuring quality of care to reduce information asymmetry.
- Aligning incentives by rewarding doctors for delivering high-quality care, not just quantity.