Lecture 11 - Self-enforcing Contracts Flashcards
Mechanisms for enforcing agreement to cooperate & coordinate
- Law, courts, ultimately backed up by state power
- Trust
- Social norms
- The Blockchain
- Adopting a “WE-attitude”
o Internalize the goals of the relationship - Self-enforcing agreements
- Reputation
- Threats backed up by private power (e.g., hierarchy)
Contractual hazards
Contractual hazards: Problem of opportunism, moral hazard, hold up
- How are these hazards avoided?
- We already looked at contractual safeguards, such as
o Contacting with multiple suppliers (Cluj Hardware)
o Termination for convenience clauses (franchising)
o Owning assets used by supplier (franchising, some supplier relations)
Mechanisms for enforcing good behavior
- The state (formal contracts)
- Formal relational contracting
- Irreversible threats
- Hostages
1st mechanism: The state (formal contracts)
- Contractual compliance, and good behaviors more generally, enforced by the state
- Law, police, courts, surveillance… ultimately the state’s monopoly on violence
“Shading”
- Shading: Dissatisfied party cuts down on cooperativeness, ceases to be proactive, doesn’t invest in the relationship
o Not really opportunism or moral hazard; happens because the party isn’t getting the outcome it expected from the deal and feels the other party is to blame
Moral hazard: exploiting asymmetric information
- Reciprocal shading: parties hit a “bad” equilibrium (that they cannot escape) or the reciprocal shading behavior becomes a death spiral
2nd mechanism: Formal relational contracting / “We” mentality
- Adopt a ”What’s in it for We” mentality.
- Transparency about aspirations, goals and concerns—e.g., by having relevant counterparts from the different companies mutually clarify this.
- Co-create the goals of the relation.
- Adopt guiding principles designed to prevent hold-up and shading: honesty, loyalty, integrity, etc. and mechanisms that ensure that the parties live up to the principles.
- These guiding principles are court-enforceable if they are written down!
o In the U.S. and partly in Denmark
3rd mechanism: Irreversible threats
To make a threat credible, a player must make an irreversible commitment that changes his or her incentives or constrains his or her action.
Example:
- In 1519, Captain Hernán Cortés landed in Veracruz to begin his great conquest of Mexico.
- One of the first actions of Cortés, was to order the sinking of his ships so there would be no option for his men but to continue. The sinking would set an irreversible course for the conqueror.
If you enter our industry, we will smash you with a price war
4th mechanism: Hostages
- Chapter 8 example: Hold-up problem: In the equilibrium of the game, the efficient investment will not be made (0,0).
- But what if the downstream firm posts a valuable ”hostage” (e.g., a bank deposit) before the game starts.
- The hostage —a credible commitment —is forfeit in the event of contract breach.
o E.g. swapping shares (e.g., recent deal between SKT, KaKao) … self-enforcing deal!
Example
- The hostage/deposit should be at least $30 to make the two options equally attractive
The basic (simple) idea of self-enforcing agreements
Underlying self-enforcing agreements is that parties make ”cheating” (engaging in moral hazard, opportunism) expensive.
Definition: Self-enforcing agreement
Self-enforcing agreement: An agreement or contract between two parties that is enforced only by those two parties (third party enforcement is not involved). This agreement stands so long the parties believe it is beneficial and is not breached by either party
The Folk Theorem
All positive payoff combinations can be sustained as equilibrium in a repeated prisoners’ dilamma setting
Resolves the prisoners’ dilemma because:
it introduces reciprocity (i.e., current bad behavior can be punished in the future) in the player’s strategies.
Strategies in repeated games
Tit-for-tat strategy:
Start playing nicely (S); subsequently choose the same action that the other player just took.
The grim strategy:
Start playing nicely (S); continue to do so as long as the other player plays nicely (S). If he plays badly (T), reciprocate with bad (T) forever.
- Stronger threat, useful to signal that this is the strategy you will play
- Signal by getting a reputation of over the top retaliation, or state publicly your commitment to the strategy
Whether they will bring the optimal choices depends on the costs and benefits of you making the choice T when the other player retaliates with the grim strategy:
- If the benefit (first column) is greater than the sum of all the future costs, you will play T
- If the sum of all the future costs are greater than the benefit, you will play S
Determinants of stability
- Costs and benefits of ending a relationship:
o The interest rate (discount factor for the future cashflows)
o The profile of costs and benefits across time - The history of the relationship:
o E.g., given one person using the grim strategy, a relationship is hard to restore, once it is damaged - Observability of decisions
- Hostages in the relation
When to use self-enforcing contracts depending on frequency & asset specificity
High frequency
Medium & High asset specificity
Self-enforcing agreements can potentially even work in situations with high asset specificity, b/c there’s too much at stake for both parties to behave badly
Advantages of self-enforcing agreements
- Save on transaction costs
o Contract drafting costs
o Costs of using third-party enforcement - Allows for contracting when third-party enforcement is not possible
- Allows for more flexibility
- Sometimes more incompleteness is better than less, e.g., when
o Clauses can be used as levers for opportunism (e.g., cost-plus contracts)
o The prevailing contract law insists on full adherence to the terms of the contract
o The parties expect that they will only know later what exactly they need, want
Because of such advantages, parties will usually try to make their agreements self-enforcing, i.e., structure agreements so that the gain from hold-up < loss
Hence, many business contracts are highly incomplete (or even no formal contract)
Vertical integration then only takes place when, under high levels of asset specificity, contracts are pushed out of their self-enforcing range
- E.g., because of unforeseen changes to legislation, customers’ wants/preferences
- Gain from hold-up > the other party’s sanction