Free Movement of Goods Flashcards
Art 3 TFEU
- The Union’s aim is to promote peace, its values and the well-being of its peoples…
- The Union shall establish an internal market. It shall work for the sustainable development of Europe based on balanced economic growth and price stability, a highly competitive social market economy, aiming at full employment and social progress, and a high level of protection and improvement of the quality of the environment. It shall promote scientific and technological advance. It shall combat social exclusion and discrimination, and shall promote social justice and protection, equality between women and men, solidarity between generations and protection of the rights of the child. It shall promote economic, social and territorial cohesion, and solidarity among Member States. It shall respect its rich cultural and linguistic diversity, and shall ensure that Europe’s cultural heritage is safeguarded and enhanced….
My thoughts: from this we can say that the internal market is not an end in itself, but it is clear that it lies at the heart of the EU’s activities.
Art 26(2) TFEU
• The internal market shall comprise an area without internal frontiers in which the free movement of goods, persons, services and capital is ensured in accordance with the provisions of the Treaties.
Art 26(2) TFEU
Economic rationale
Economic rationale: the internal market is designed to ensure competition, leading to technical innovation from firms seeking a comparative advantage and lower prices. The idea is that ultimately there will be better goods at lower prices —a large benefit to consumers.
Art 26(2) TFEU
Implementation of measures designed to regulate the internal market
Gebhard (1995) -
a case on the freedom of establishment: “It follows… from the Court’ s case-law that national measures liable to hinder or make less attractive the exercise of fundamental freedoms guaranteed by the Treaty must fulfil four conditions:
- they must be applied in a non-discriminatory manner;
- they must be justified by imperative requirements in the general interest;
- they must be suitable for securing the attainment of the objective which they pursue;
- and they must not go beyond what is necessary in order to attain it”
Imports: Art. 34 TFEU:
Quantitative restrictions on imports and all measures having equivalent effect shall be prohibited between Member States.
Art. 35 TFEU
Quantitative restrictions on exports, and all measures having equivalent effect, shall be prohibited between Member States
Derogations: Art. 36 TFEU
The provisions of Articles 34 and 35 shall not preclude prohibitions or restrictions on imports, exports or goods in transit justified on grounds of public morality, public policy or public security; the protection of health and life of humans, animals or plants; the protection of national treasures possessing artistic, historic or archaeological value; or the protection of industrial and commercial property. Such prohibitions or restrictions shall not, however, constitute a means of arbitrary discrimination or a disguised restriction on trade between Member States.
The fundamental idea here is balance: the articles are concerned with balancing: (i) impetus towards free trade; with (ii) accepting that MS retain a strictly defined competence to lawfully restrict free trade to protect certain important domestic interests. To make this more vivid: consider a country banning the import of porn in the interest of public morality.
Quantitative restrictions
“measures which amount to a total or partial restraint of, according to the circumstances, imports, exports, or goods in transit.” C/273 Geddo v Ente [1973] ECR 865. This includes bans on imports and imposed quotas on imports.
Measures having equivalent effect (MEQR’s)
“not only take the form of restraint described: whatever the description or technique employed, they can also consist of encumbrances having the same effect.” (Geddo). We need to consider what this means in more detail:
• Directive 70/50: this is no longer applicable, but continues to give some idea of the scope of MEQR’s. The directive identified two groups of such measures:
o Distinctly applicable measures (Art. 2 of directive): these do not apply equally to domestic and imported goods (e.g. they make importation more difficult / costly relative to domestic products) —e.g. higher standards for imported goods.
o Indistinctly applicable measures (Art. 3 of directive) these measures appear on their face to be equally applicable to domestic and imported goods, but the effect of the measure disadvantages imported goods by requiring them to satisfy a domestic set of rules for similar products —e.g. conditions on the packaging / composition of goods.
ECJ in Dassonville
• here the ECJ give an effect based definition — i.e. if a national measure has a prejudicial effect to the internal market, unconcerned with intention: “all trading rules enacted by Member States which are capable of hindering, directly or indirectly, actually or potentially, intra-Community trade.”
CAT 1: PHYSICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE AND DISCRIMINATORY PRACTICES
This is the category of measures that fall under Art. 2 of Directive 70/50. This type of barrier was characteristic of the earlier cases, where relatively easy-to-identify interferences with trade integration were attacked. This category does not apply to goods with distinctive characteristics that may be national or regional in origin —e.g. Stilton Cheese, Parma Ham etc.
CAT 1: PHYSICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE AND DISCRIMINATORY PRACTICES
Imposing additional requirements on imported goods
Case 251/78 Firma Denkavit Futtermittel GmbH v Minister fur Ernahgrung (1979
the requirement that imported goods should be inspected was held to breach Art. 34 because of the delays in inspection process and increased transport costs.
CAT 1: PHYSICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE AND DISCRIMINATORY PRACTICES
National rules giving preferences to domestic goods
Commission v Ireland (1980)
Facts: The “Irish Souvenirs” case. Ireland passed a law requiring imported jewellery bearing certain motifs or characteristics to be sold as souvenirs to bear the word ‘foreign’ if not produced in Ireland.
ECJ: “
• The orders concerned in the present case are not measures which are applicable to domestic products and to imported products without distinction but rather a set of rules which apply only to imported products and are therefore discriminatory in nature” [9]
• The measure was discriminatory because “the essential characteristic of the souvenirs in question is that they constitute a pictorial reminder of the place visited which does not by itself mean that a souvenir, as defined in the orders, must necessarily be manufactured in the country of origin.” [15]
• Would be nothing wrong with leaving “domestic manufacturers to take appropriate steps such as affixing, if they so wished, their mark of origin to their own products of packaging.” [16]
CAT 1: PHYSICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE AND DISCRIMINATORY PRACTICES
Restricting channels for the distribution of imported goods
Case 8/74 Procureur de Roi v Dassonville [1974] ECR 837
ECJ held that a Belgian requirement that importers of Scotch whisky possess a British certificate of authentication was incompatible with Art. 34 TFEU. Belgians had imported Scotch whisky from free circulation in France. The rule favoured direct importers over traders importing Scotch whisky into Belgium from other MS in which the goods were already in free circulation. This ‘channelled’ trade and distorted the market.
• [5] A distorting measure is: “all trading rules enacted by Member States which are capable of hindering, directly or indirectly, actually or potentially, intra-Community trade.”
• [6] “In the absence of a Community system guaranteeing for consumers the authenticity of a product’s designation of origin, if a MS takes measures to prevent unfair practices in this connexion, it is however subject to the condition that these measures should be reasonable and that the means of proof required should not act as a hindrance to trade between MS and should, in consequence, be accessible to all Community nationals.”
• [7] Art 36 does not apply to arbitrary discrimination or disguised restrictions on trade
• [8] “That may be the case with formalities, required by a MS for the purpose of proving the origin of a product, which only direct importers are really in a position to satisfy without facing serious difficulties.”
CAT 1: PHYSICAL BARRIERS TO TRADE AND DISCRIMINATORY PRACTICES
Licences
International Fruit Company v Produktschap voor Froenten en Fruit (No 2) (1971):
Facts: Court asked to consider whether Art. 34 applies to “national legislative provisions prohibiting imports and exports without a licence but which in fact are not applied because exemptions are granted from the prohibition and, there this is not so, because the licence is always granted on request”
ECJ:
• Noted that: “Apart from the exceptions for which provision is made by Community law itself those provisions preclude the application to intra-Community trade of a national provisions which requires, even purely as a formality, import or export licences or any other similar procedure”
• More permissive approach to lawfulness of controls over trade with third countries outside the EU
CAT 2: PROTECTIONIST EFFECTS FROM NATIONAL LAW DISPARITIES
This is the category of measures that fall into Art. 3 of Directive 50/70 (indistinctly applicable rules). Even though there might be no explicit reference to the origin of goods, disparities between national laws may themselves generate measures having equivalent effect within the meaning of Art. 34 TFEU.
CAT 2: PROTECTIONIST EFFECTS FROM NATIONAL LAW DISPARITIES
Cassis de Dijon
This was a crucial development, since it concerns controlling national regulatory autonomy in establishing technical standards in so far as it may impede European market building.
Facts: A German law specified a minimum alcohol level of 25% for certain spirits including cassis (made in France). The law was indistinctly applicable because it applied to both domestic and imported liqueurs, but had the effect of impeding the importation of French cassis which had alcohol content between 15% and 20%.
ECJ: accepted that the German requirement amounted to an MEQR.
• 14: “In practice, the principal effect of requirements of this nature is to promote alcoholic beverages having a high alcohol content by excluding from the national market products of other MS which do not answer that description.
• It therefore appears that the unilateral requirement imposed by the rules of a MS of a minimum alcohol content for the purposes of the sale of alcoholic beverages constitutes an obstacle to trade which is incompatible with [Art 34]
• There is therefore no valid reason why, provided that they have been lawfully produced and marketed in one o the MS, alcoholic beverages should not be introduced into any other MS; the sale of such products may not be subject to a legal prohibition on the marketing of beverages with an alcohol content lower than the limit set by national rules.”
CAT 2: PROTECTIONIST EFFECTS FROM NATIONAL LAW DISPARITIES
Minimum fat requirement in cheese
Case 286/86 Deserbais (1988)
Facts: French legislation restricted use of the name ‘Edam’ to choose with a minimum fat content of 40%. D imported cheese from Germany where it was lawfully produced with a lower fat content. D marketed the cheese as ‘Edam’ and was prosecuted for unlawful use of a trade name. D argued Art 34 provided him with a complete defence to the charge.
ECJ:
• [12] “It would be incompatible with [Art 34]… and the objectives of a common market to apply such rules to imported cheeses of the same type where those cheeses have been lawfully produced and marketed in another MS under the same generic name but with a different minimum fat content. The MS into which they are imported cannot prevent the importation and marketing of such cheeses where adequate information for the consumer is ensured.”
• 13: Question may arise if same rule must be applied where a product under a name is so different (in terms of composition or production) from products generally known by the name that it cannot be regarded as falling within the same category. But this case is not such a case. NB: there could be a case where a such a rule was legitimate.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
This is where obstacles to commerce diminish the overall volume of trade, but do not affect imports more than domestic products. Such measures are not caught by Art. 34.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Background: Sunday Trading cases
Case 145/88 Torfaen BC v B&Q plc (1989)
Facts: B & Q was prosecuted for violating the Shops Act 1950 by allowing its retail premises to be open on Sunday other than for limited range of permitted transactions under that Act. B&Q argued that ‘Sunday trading’ depressed sales, including sales of imported products.
ECJ:
• 11: “National rules prohibiting retailers from opening their premises on Sunday apply to imported and domestic products alike. In principle, the marketing of products imported from other Member States is not therefore made more difficult than the marketing of domestic products.”
• But failed to differentiate with Cassis de Dijon… 13: Art 34 “must be interpreted as meaning that the prohibition which it lays down does not apply to national rules prohibiting retailers from opening their premises on Sunday where the restrictive effects on Community trade which may result therefrom do not exceed the effects intrinsic to rules of that kind”
This led to confusion because the ECJ treated the Sunday trading rules as MEQRs falling within the Art 34 structure, but left it to national courts to decide whether or not the restriction on trade was necessary and proportionate.Confusion at national level followed, where different English and Welsh courts adopted different views of the compatibility of Sunday trading with the Treaty.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Background: Sunday Trading cases
Case C-169/91 Stoke on Trent and Norwich City Councils v B&Q (1992):
17: Art 34 “is to be interpreted as meaning that the prohibition which it lays down does not apply to national legislation prohibiting shops from opening on Sundays.”
The importance of these cases was that in the decade preceding them, the court allowed invocation of Art. 34 where the application of rules and their consequential burdens were felt equally by both domestic and international goods. Weatherill: the ECJ got these cases ‘spectacularly wrong’ by finding that they could be within the scope of Art. 34.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
The rule in Keck
Facts: K and M resold goods at a loss. This violated French law forbidding such practices. K and M submitted the law restricted the volume of sales of imported goods by depriving them of a method of sales promotion [Art 34].
ECJ: any restrictive effect plainly effected all goods, not just imports. [Outside scope of Art 34]
• [13] “Such legislation may … restrict the volume of sales, and hence the volume of sales of products from other Member States, in so far as it deprives traders of a method of sales promotion. But the question remains whether such a possibility is sufficient to characterize the legislation in question as a measure having equivalent effect to a quantitative restriction on imports.”
• [14] “In view of the increasing tendency of traders to invoke [Art 34] of the Treaty as a means of challenging any rules whose effect is to limit their commercial freedom even where such rules are not aimed at products from other Member States, the Court considers it necessary to re-examine and clarify its case-law on this matter.”
• [16] “… contrary to what has previously been decided, the application to products from other Member States of national provisions restricting or prohibiting certain selling arrangements is not such as to hinder directly or indirectly, actually or potentially, trade between Member States within the meaning of the Dassonville judgment, so long as those provisions apply to all relevant traders operating within the national territory and so long as they affect in the same manner, in law and in fact, the marketing of domestic products and of those from other Member States.”
Thus, two conditions were laid down to prove a measure is a selling arrangement outside the scope of Art. 34: (i) the measure applies to all affected traders operating within the national territory; and (ii) the measure affects in the same manner in law and in fact the marketing of domestic and imported products.
Thus, as in Keck, matters satisfying the two requirements are not the concern of EU law and lie in the hands of the local regulator.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Examples of selling arrangements
Cases C-401 & 402/92 Criminal Proceedings against Tankstation ‘t Heukstevof and JBE Boermans (1994):
Dutch rules required the closure of all petrol stations at night, and applied to all traders operating in the national territory—these were not caught by Art 34. The rules affected domestic and foreign producers in the same way in law and fact.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Examples of selling arrangements
Case C-71/02 Herbert Karner v Troostwijk (2004)
An Austrian restriction on the advertising of auctions of goods bought from insolvent firms, which had the aim of preventing consumers being given a misleading impression about potential prices, was seen as a selling arrangement and not caught by Art 34.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Complications in application —advertising
These cases disprove the 2003 assertion of the Commission that “the court has completed its case law” in this area.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Case C-405/98 Konsunemtombudsmannen v Gourmet Int’l Products (2001)
Facts: the Swedish government restricted the advertising of alcoholic drinks on radio and TV and in magazines and other publications, unless the magazine was distributed solely at the point of sale of the beverage. Gourmet published a magazine that reached members of the public and that contained advertisements for alcohol in breach of the Swedish legislation.
ECJ:
• This type of selling arrangement had to be considered within Art 34 structure of analysis. The arrangement impeded access by foreign producers to the alcoholic beverage market more than domestic producers because consumers would be more familiar with domestic goods. Thus the arrangement was under Cassis category. National court left to determine if it was justifiable.
• “Even without its being necessary to carry out a precise analysis of the facts …, which it is for the national court to do, the Court is able to conclude that, in the case of products like alcoholic beverages, the consumption of which is linked to traditional social practices and to local habits and customs, a prohibition of all advertising directed at consumers in the form of advertisements in the press, on the radio and on television, the direct mailing of unsolicited material or the placing of posters on the public highway is liable to impede access to the market by products from other Member States more than it impedes access by domestic products, with which consumers are instantly more familiar.”
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Case C-239/02 Douwe-Egberts [2004] ECR I-7007
Facts: The ECJ was asked whether the Belgian law, which provides for an outright ban of any references to slimming on foodstuffs labelling, infringes EU law including the principles of the free movement of goods.
ECJ:
• [52] “… the possibility cannot be ruled out that to compel a producer to discontinue an advertising scheme which he considers to be particularly effective may constitute an obstacle to imports”.
• [53] “Moreover, an absolute prohibition of advertising the characteristics of a product is liable to impede access to the market by products from other Member States more than it impedes access by domestic products, with which consumers are more familiar” (Gourmet International Products).
The point is not that any rule affecting advertising or other methods of boosting sales is within the scope of Art. 34 —rather, it seems to be that one must carefully examine the impact of a particular challenged national measure on the market which it affects:
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Herbert Karner v Troostwijk (2004)
Here there was not a total ban on advertisements (there was an alternative means of advertising available) therefore access to the domestic market for importers was not made more difficult.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
A-Punkt Schmuckhandels v Claudia Schmidt “Schmidt” [2006]
“the fact that a marketing method is apparently more efficient and profitable is not a sufficient reason to assert that the national provision prohibiting it is caught by the prohibition laid down in [Art 34]. Such a provision constitutes a measure having equivalent effect only if the exclusion of the relevant marketing method affects products from other Member States more than it affects domestic products”
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Application to restrictions on the use of products
Oliver and Enchelmaier
the limiting effect of Keck may be undone if the court is too quick to allow review of these types of national measures.
The Court seems to apply Keck very literally —i.e. it only applies to restrictions concerning sale and not use. But the reasoning is opaque and no clear rationale is given. In Keck the ECJ noted ‘the increasing tendency of traders to challenge national rules’ and drew a distinction between product requirements and certain selling arrangements (CSAs). Product requirements would always fall within the scope of EU law and have to be justified but not so CSAs. So long as the CSAs applied equally to all traders in the national territory and had the same effect on all traders in law and in fact, they fell outside the scope of the Treaty.
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Case C-110/05 Commission v Italy [2009] - ECR I-519
Facts: Italy prohibited motorcycles, mopeds etc. from towing trailers, even those specifically designed for use with such vehicles. Commission argued this breached Art 34.
ECJ: this law fell within Art 34 but justified on grounds of public safety [69].
• 33: Quoted Dassonville para 5 (see ablove)
• 34: Art 34 “reflects the obligation to respect the principles of non-discrimination and of mutual recognition of products lawfully manufactured and marketed in other MS, as well as the principle of ensuring free access of Community products to national markets.”
• 35: In absence of harmonisation “obstacles to the free movement of goods which are the consequence of applying, to goods coming from other MS where they are lawfully manufactured and marketed, rules that lay down requirements to be met by such goods constitute measures of equivalent effect to quantitative restrictions even if those rules apply to all products alike.”
• 36: Contrasts with Keck but gives no reasons at all justifying the contrast.
• 37: “Consequently, measures adopted by a MS the object or effect of which is to treat products coming from other MS less favourably are to be regarded as measures having equivalent effect to quantitative restrictions”
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Case C-142/05 Aklagaren v Mickelsson, Roos [2009] ECR I-4273
Factually similar to the Italian Trailers case. Swedish rules restricted the use of jet-skis on waterways that are not generally navigable.
ECJ: was within Art 34, but justified by need to protect the environment. ECJ left Sweden some leeway in application, but the regulatory choices can be supervised under Art 34.
• [26] “Even if the national regulations at issue do not have the aim or effect of treating goods coming from other Member States less favourably, which is for the national court to ascertain, the restriction which they impose on the use of a product in the territory of a Member State may, depending on its scope, have a considerable influence on the behaviour of consumers, which may, in turn, affect the access of that product to the market of that Member State (Commission v Italy, paragraph 56)”
• [27] “Consumers, knowing that the use permitted by such regulations is very limited, have only a limited interest in buying that product (see to that effect, Commission v Italy, para 57).”
• [28] “In that regard, where the national regulations for the designation of navigable waters and waterways have the effect of preventing users of personal watercraft from using them for the specific and inherent purposes for which they were intended or of greatly restricting their use, which is for the national court to ascertain, such regulations have the effect of hindering the access to the domestic market in question for those goods and therefore constitute, save where there is a justification pursuant to [Art 36] or there are overriding public interest requirements, measures having equivalent effect to quantitative restrictions on imports prohibited by [Art 34].”
CAT 3: SELLING ARRANGEMENTS
Spalding case note on Trailers and Roos:
• In the 1990s the European Court of Justice (ECJ) established a distinction between the product requirements and certain selling arrangements in the case of Keck and Mithouard.
• A few years ago in Trailers the ECJ declined to extend Keck to user arrangements and declared that a measure will be classified as a measure having equivalent effect to a quantitative restriction if it hinders access to the market.
• In the Trailers the ECJ found that the rule did not discriminate with regard to origin but in fact only imports were affected as no trailers were manufactured in Italy. The ECJ identified three situations where a rule could be regarded a MEQR.
1. Where the object/effect of the measure is to treat products from other member states less favourably than domestic products.
2. When a measure requires goods lawfully made in another member state to meet another condition even if it applies to all products indiscriminately.
3. Any other measure which hinders the access of products originating in other member states to the market.
• The third situation applied in Trailers as the prohibition on the use of the product would have a big impact on consumer behaviour which will affect demand for the product. However this could be justified under the mandatory requirement of road safety.
• A second user arrangement case emerged soon after. In Mickelsson and Roos —here ECJ did not even refer to Keck but went straight to the definition of a MEQR provided in the Trailers case. It found such a limitation would hinder access to the market as it would deter consumers from buying the product but it could be justified on the grounds of the protection of health and life of plants and animals and environmental protection.
• It would appear that although Keck applies where the question is as to certain selling arrangements, it does not apply to restrictions on the use of products. Instead, here, we get the ‘considerable influence over the consumer’ test.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
General
Art. 36 TFEU
The provisions of Articles 34 and 35 shall not preclude prohibitions or restrictions on imports, exports or goods in transit justified on grounds of public morality, public policy or public security; the protection of health and life of humans, animals or plants; the protection of national treasures possessing artistic, historic or archaeological value; or the protection of industrial and commercial property. Such prohibitions or restrictions shall not, however, constitute a means of arbitrary discrimination or a disguised restriction on trade between Member States. THIS APPLIES TO CAT 1 AND CAT 2 —NOT TO CAT 3.
The effect of the Treaty is thus not an out and out declaration that trade barriers are legal per se. The key is that they must be shown to be justified and the burden of proof is on the regulator (i.e. the member state). The aim of the internal market is not remorseless deregulation— rather it is to achieve a balance between the EU’s aim to establish an internal market and the national regulatory autonomy of MS.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Public morality
Henn and Darby (1979
Concerned a UK ban on the import of obscene films and magazines. Although this constituted a obstacle to the internal market simpliciter Art. 36 could be relied on by the UK: “ it for each MS to determine in accordance with its own scale of values and in the form selected by it the requirements of public morality.” Thus, there was no unlawful discrimination because there was no lawful trade of such goods at all in the UK
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Public morality
Conegate v HM Customs & Excise Commissioners (1986
The UK sought to prevent the import of life-size inflatable ‘love-love’ dolls from Germany. ECJ held that the derogation was not available to the UK. The same goods could be lawfully manufactured in the UK. The ban arbitrarily discriminated against imported goods.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Public policy
R v Thompson (1978
This is construed very narrowly, having been invoked successfully only once in an Art. 35 (export of goods) case:
UK banned export of silver coins to prevent them being melted down or destroyed. There was also a ban in the UK on such coins being melted down or destroyed. ECJ accepted the ban stemmed from the need of the state to protect the right to mint coinage, which involved a fundamental interest of the state.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Public policy
Cullett v Centre Leclerc Toulouse (1985)
Leclerc group started selling petrol at prices below those set by French law. Competitor brought proceedings against Leclerc on basis of French law. Leclerc argued the minimum price law infringed Art 24 as it allowed authorities to manipulate prices and prevent importers entering market. French government argued public policy derogation applied on account of threat to public order and security that would result from local retailers if faced with unrestricted competition. ECJ rejected the argument — the French government had not proved it could not deal with these threats or possible disruptions using traditional means at its disposal.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Public security
Campus Oil v Minister for Industry and Energy (1984):
Ireland is completely dependent on imports for petroleum supply. It required importers to buy 35% of requirements from a state-owned oil refinery at prices the Irish government fixed. ECJ: this was an MEQR but the restriction was necessary on grounds of public security. Because of the exceptional importance of petroleum products as an energy source, an interruption in supplies could seriously affect public security. The restriction allowed Ireland to maintain its own oil refining capacity and was proportional.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
This is the most frequently invoked derogation. It applies in the absence of harmonised measures —e.g. to deal with a crisis such as BSE or foot and mouth. The ECJ demands objective evidence, however, if it is to allow for a derogation.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
Case 178/84 Commission v Germany “Beer Purity” case [1987]
The German government banned the marketing of beer containing all additives on the ground that the long-term effect of additives was not known. ECJ examined the scientific evidence and found there was little evidence that additives presented a risk to public health. I.e. good example of the requirement of objective evidence.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
If the scientific evidence is actually inconclusive, the ECJ will allow MS to decide if the degree of health protection is required:
Santoz (1983)
Santoz (1983)
Dutch authorities refused to grant authorisation for the import of muesli bars with
added vitamins from Germany. ECJ accepted the dearth of scientific evidence about vitamins meant that the Dutch restriction was justified.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
Arbitrary measures will not be tolerated:
Commission v UK (1982)
The UK banned the import of poultry products from MS shortly before Xmas in 1981. ECJ held this was a disguised restriction on trade. The measures were hastily introduced to coincide with Xmas. Government had reacted to UK turkey producers’ fear of imports from France. There were no genuine health reasons for the restriction.
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
derogation has been applied broadly —i.e. to allow environmental regulations:
Case C-379/98 PreussenElektra v Schhleswag [2001]
German law required electricity distribution undertakings to purchase at fixed minimum prices electricity produced from renewable energy sources in their area of supply in Germany. ECJ: the legislative policy was justified as it was designed to protect the health and life of humans, plants and animals. Renewable energy reduces greenhouse gas emission. (73) Art 11 TFEU requires environmental protection to be integrated into the definition and implementation of other Community policies. (76)
JUSTIFICATIONS IN THE RESTRICTION OF THE FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Art. 36 for Cat 1 and Cat 2
- Protection of health and life of humans, animals, or plants
NB: Sometimes lack of harmonisation at Community level justifies MS in making their own determinations in interest of citizen health:
Case 53/80 Eyssen [1981] ECR 409
Facts: Netherlands manufacturer produced cheese for sale domestically and in other MS containing an additive (nisin) that was illegal in the Netherlands only for products intended for sale on the domestic market.
• 10: No uniform rules on nisin amongst MS.
• 11: “In view of this disparity of rule it cannot be disputed that the prohibition by certain MS… is of such a nature to affect imports of that product from other MS where… the addition of nisin is… permitted and that it for that reason constituted a measure having an effect equivalent to a quantitative restriction.”
• 12: Studies “have not as yet enabled absolutely certain conclusions to be drawn regarding the maximum quantity of nisin which a person may consume daily without serious risk to his health” because “the assessment of the risk connected with the consumption of the additive depends upon several factors of a variable nature” e.g. dietary habits in a particular MS. Each MS prescribes maximums based on dietary habits of its citizens in relation to other products they might consume which contain nisin too.
• 14: “The difficulties and uncertainties inherent in such an assessment may explain the lack of uniformity in the national laws of the MS… and at the same time justify the limited scope which the prohibition of the use of the additive in a given product… has in certain MS.” The Netherlands law makes an assessment fro Dutch citizens, but allows export of more nisin so other MS can determine their own relevant conclusions.
• 15: Directive explicitly allows MS to make their own nisin determinations.
• 16: “Whilst it has the effect of hindering trade between MS in the products concerned [the national legislation] is included amongst the measures which Art 36 of the Treaty permits MS to adopt on rounds of the protection of health of humans and for that reason it escapes the prohibitions.”
Special justifications applying to category 2
- The presumption of mutual recognition
Case 120/78 Cassis de Dijon [1979] ECR 649 “
There is therefore no valid reason why, provided they have been lawfully produced and marketed in one of the MS, alcoholic beverages should not be introduced into any other MS”
The principle is that if goods have been lawfully produced and marketed in MS 1, they can in principle be sold in MS 2 without further restriction. There is thus a presumption that rules which imposed a dual burden on the producer, who would have to satisfy MS 1 and MS 2’s rules would infringe Art. 34. Thus, the MS would have to rely on either an Art. 36 derogation, or the ‘rule of reason’ (see below —also developed in Cassis).
Special justifications applying to category 2
- The presumption of mutual recognition
Verein gegen Unwesen in Handel und Gewerbe Koln v Mars (1995)
A sales promotion in which Mars sold ice cream bars 10% larger than usual size and marked the wrappers “10%” was challenged by consumer authorities in Germany on grounds that it created impression that 10% increase was free and the graphic made the bar seem bigger than it was. Mars challenged this. ECJ: as the bars were being sold throughout the EU they must also be sold in Germany on the basis of the dual burden rule. Court concluded the wrappers were part of the product. Manufacturer would otherwise have to change wrappers at the border or have a second production line for Germany.
Special justifications applying to category 2
- The rule of reason
The Rule of Reason is essentially the proposition that a proportionality exercise must be performed by the Court to determine whether the effects of Member State legislation on the free movement of goods is justified in light of the legislation’s stated goals. Following Cassis a MS can point to the following as justifications as to why a derogation is justified: (i) effectiveness of fiscal supervisions; (ii) protection of public health; (iii) fairness of commercial transactions; (iv) defence of the consumer.
Special justifications applying to category 2
- The rule of reason
Case 120/78 Cassis de Dijon [1979] ECR 649
The German government sought to justify the minimum alcohol requirement in two ways:
- the rule helped prevent alcoholism by restricting low-alcohol beverages that induced alcohol tolerance.
- necessary for protection of consumers: those with less alcohol enjoyed a competitive advantage since they could price lower.
ECJ at para 8 mentioned mandatory requirements which went beyond Art 36 and could save an MEQR: “Obstacles to movement within the Community resulting from disparities between the national laws relating to the marketing of the products in question must be accepted in so far as those provisions may be recognized as being necessary in order to satisfy mandatory requirements relating in particular to the effectiveness of fiscal supervision, the protection of public health, the fairness of commercial transactions and the defence of the consumer.”
However, this was not the case here:
1. Wrong because other low-alcohol content products were widely available on the German market.
2. Wrong because labelling requirements could ensure consumers were aware of the alcohol content of products and so make an informed decision about whether to purchase more expensive high alcohol spirits, or cheaper lower alcohol spirits.
The ambit of the ‘rule of reason’ or ‘mandatory requirements’ is limited —they can only be pleaded where an indistinctly applicable MEQR is in question (and the principle of proportionality must be adhered to).
Further, they are not exhaustive (the ECJ said ‘in particular’ in Cassis) —one other factor that can be pointed to is the protection of the environment. However, the ECJ is not prepared to endlessly expand their scope.
Special justifications applying to category 2
- The rule of reason
Case C-379/98 PreussenElektra v Schhleswag [2001] ECR I-2099
ECJ: simply ignored the recommendation of AG Jacobs that the mandatory requirement of environmental protection should be capable of being invoked for distinctly applicable measures. AG Jacobs had based his recommendation on the contention that the ECJ had relied on the mandatory requirement in 4 earlier cases which in his views were doubtedly indistinctly applicable. The ECJ instead held that the measure in question here was distinctly applicable and so the Art. 36 derogation to protect the health and life of humans, animals and plants applied