EC201 Micro Flashcards
SR v LR distinction
SR: period of time where one or more of a firm’s inputs cannot be changed
No opp.cost in SR -> one price for everything
LR: period of time in which all inputs can be changed
All opp.cost -> multiple prices
Profit Maximisation: Standard Assumption
- Profits = revenue - opportunity cost
- Objective of shareholders who control the firm and do not work for the firm
- Simple model starts with a production function or cost function
- Ignores the fact that the firm is an organisation run by people who have individual objectives and agendas
- Ignores conflicts of interest between investors and senior managers
- Competition: if a firm can at best make zero profit, it has to maximise profits to stay in business
- Incentives generated by the financial sector and the market for managers (reputation, reward packages, takeover threat)
Risk Taking
- Risk management is necessary
- Managing the risks of long term decisions is difficult
- Some incentive schemes, e.g. bonuses and stock options may encourage risk taking
- The situation is complicated by asymmetric information and incomplete contracts
- Carney: “Compensation schemes overvalued the present and heavily discounted the future, encouraging imprudent risk taking and short-termism”
PDV of Profits
- Standard assumption that firms maximise the present discounted value V of profits,
- Measuring revenue can be problematic “principally due to the accelerated recognition of commercial income and delayed accrual of costs”
- Costs are complicated if the firm has durable equipment, intellectual property or long run contracts
- Economic cost (opportunity cost) can be different from cash flows to providers of inputs and from accounting costs
Opportunity Cost (Economic Cost)
- Defined as the value of an input in its best alternative use
- For something a person or firm is buying now, the opportunity cost is the current price
- Can be impossible to measure accurately but useful to think about when making decisions
The Cost of Capital
- If you save p at interest rate r for 1 year you have cash (1+r)p next year
- If you buy the capital good, used it and sold it, you would have cash p next year
- The difference in the amount of cash is the opportunity cost of capital rp
- If p = 1 the cost of capital is r
- The cost of capital depends on: rate of physical or technical deterioration, continuation or not of technical support, technical obsolescence, changes in the price of the capital good, installation and transaction costs
- Taxes
Why do management practices differ across firms and countries?
- Good management makes a big difference to profits and other measures
- Huge variation across and within countries and industries
- Competition is associated with good management
- Monitoring, targets and incentives
Low cost of capital firms: badly managed firms?
- If capital is obsolete (ood) it may have zero or even negative opportunity cost (pay to scrap it)
- Land may have opportunity cost but that is ignored because there is no associated cash flow -> land is a fixed factor of production
- Firm may continue even though it’s making an economic loss. Low debt avoids cash flow problems
- Appointing eldest son as CEO is associated with bad management
Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns
• If one input increases while the others are held constant, the marginal product of that input falls as output expands
• Example: labour in agriculture
With a fixed amount of land, seed, machinery etc. beyond a certain point the extra output from increasing labour starts falling
Cost Functions
• The cost function c(v,w,q) is the minimum cost of producing output q using capital K and labour L with prices v and w
• This definition assumes all inputs can be varied (LR cost function)
• You find the cost function by:
Finding the levels of K and L that minimise vK + wL subject to the constraint f(K,L) > q and non negativity constraints K > 0, L > 0
• K(v,w,q) and L(v,w,q) -> sometimes called conditional fact demand as they depend on (v,w,q)
• The cost function is:
C(v,w,q) = vK(v,w,q) + wL(v,w,q)
• Check for: increasing inputs increases outputs, convexity
Properties of the Cost Function I (facts)
1) Increasing in output q
2) Homogeneous of degree 1 in input prices v,w (double price = double C(v,w,q))
3) Non-decreasing in input prices
4) Concave in input prices
5) Shephard’s lemma for cost functions
Properties of the Cost Function II
- Cost minimisation at a tangency
- If q2 > q1, producing q2 costs more than producing q1 so the cost function c(v,w,q2) > c(v,w,q1) the cost function is increasing in output
- Conditional factor demand K(v,w,q) & L(v,w,q) are homogeneous of degree 0 in input prices
- The input combination that minimises the cost of producing q does not change, but the cost of the inputs is multiplied by k
- If all input prices are multiplied by k > 0 the isocost line doesn’t change (homogeneous of degree 0)
- The cost function is homogenous of degree 1 in input prices
- If the price of K rises from vA to vB, the gradient of the isocost line changes, the cost of producing q1 increases
Thingies and Homogeneity
Thingy Homo
Isocost 0
Cost Function 1
CFD 0
Only the cost function is homosexual.
Low Wages and Labour Productivity
• Which way does causation go?
• Low production thus low wages
Or
• Low wages thus low production
• If wages are low then firms substitute labour for capital. The Marginal product of labour is then lower?
• Low productivity may be a consequence of low wages & high cost of capital
• Post financial crisis, harder & more expensive for firms to borrow. Low investment
Returns to Scale (check)
- A property of the production function
- With constant returns to scale, multiplying inputs by any m > 0 multiplies output by m so f(mK,mL) = mf(K,L)
- If f(mK,mL) > mf(K,L) there are increasing returns to scale
- If f(mK,mL) < mf(K,L) there are decreasing returns to scale
Economies of Scale
- A feature of a cost function
- Average cost AC = total cost/output
- There are economies of scale if AC decreases with output
- There are diseconomies of scale if AC increases with output
- Increasing returns to scale in the production function implies economies of scale
Volume Effects
- Capacity depends on volume
- Cost depends on surface area
- Increasing size reduces cost per unit of output
There can’t be decreasing returns to scale?
- There might be some fixed input that cannot be doubled
- There may be managerial diseconomies of scale -> management difficulties grow faster than the number of people
- The transition from a small to a large organisation can be difficult
Other influences on costs
- The production function assumes a single unchanging product and that the output from a given output is fixed by technology
- This may not be so owing to economies of scope/learning by doing
- Costs before production starts e.g. R&D, websites etc
Economies of scope
- One firm producing a range of related products has cost advantages over firms producing single products
- When a firm gains efficiencies from selling a wider range of products
- E.g. selling petrol and groceries at a petrol station (same input (labour and capital), can sell both types of goods for same pay)
Learning by Doing
• As firms build experience in producing a product the average cost of producing the product falls
Economic Loss
Economic loss is a term of art which refers to financial loss and damage suffered by a person such as can be seen only on a balance sheet rather than as physical injury to the person or destruction of property.
Isoquant
• Isoquants show the combinations of inputs that can produce a given quantity of output = indifference curves in consumer theory
The isoquant curve is a graph, used in the study ofmicroeconomics, that charts all inputs that produce a specified level of output. This graph is used as a metric for the influence that the inputs have on the level of output or production that can be obtained. The isoquant curve assists firms in making adjustments to inputs to maximize outputs, and thus profits. The curve represents a consistent level of output
Isocost
• Isocost lines show the combinations of inputs that cost the same = constant expenditure lines
In economics an isocost line shows all combinations of inputs which cost the same total amount. Although similar to the budget constraint in consumer theory, the use of the isocost line pertains to cost-minimization in production, as opposed to utility-maximization.
Conditional Factor Demand
• Conditional factor demand is the amount of inputs L and K that are needed to get output q at the least possible cost when the price of one unit of cap-Italy is v and the price of one unit of labour L, the wage, is w
• Conditional factor demand is at the point where lowest isocost line just meets the isoquant with output q
• Conditional factor demand K(v,w,q) and L(v,w,q) is the solution to the problem of minimising cost vK + wL subject to the output constraint f(K,L) > q and the nonnegativity constraints K > 0 and L > 0
• The assumption is that increasing one or both inputs increases output implies that the output constraint is always satirised as an equality so f(K,L) = q. The definition implies that for an L and K with f(K,L) = q
vK(v,w,q) + wL(v,w,q) < vK + wL
Conditional factor demands (k and l): A conditional factor demand is the cost-minimising level of an input (factor of production) such a labour or capital, required to produce a given level of output, for a given unit input cost (v/w) of the input factors
Homogeneity
- Conditional factor demand depends on the level of output and the input price ratio v/w which determines the gradient of the isocost lines
- Thus multiplying both input prices by a number m > - does not change v/w so does not change conditional factor demand
- Conditional factor demand is homogeneous of degree 0 in prices
- The cost function is homogenous of degree 1 in prices
- In summary multiplying both input prices by m > 0 does not change relative prices so does not change conditional factor demand, but does change the cost of conditional factor demand, that is the cost function, which is multiplied by m
- The cost function is increasing in output. The fact that because an increase in output requires an increase in one or both inputs and increase in output from q to q’ increases costs. Thus the cost function c(v,w,q) is increasing in output q
The Cost Function
• The cost function c(v,w,q) is the minimum cost needed at prices v and w to obtain output q or more by using a combination of inputs L and K that satisfy the nonnegativity constraints
• As conditional factor demand gives the quantities of L and K that minimise the cost needed to get output q at prices v and w this definition implies that:
c(v,w,q) = vK(v,w,q) + wL(v,w,q)
That is, the cost function is the cost needed to buy condition factor demand
• For any L and K with f(K,L) = q
• c(v,w,q) < vK + wL
Definition of Price Taking
- A firm is a price taker if nothing it can do affects the prices it pays for inputs and outputs
- In particular its output does not affect its output price
- Price taking does not mean prices do not change
- Price taking is plausible if the firm has a small market share
The Shutdown Rule
- If the cost of producing 0 is 0, i.e. c(v,w,0) = 0 the firm can make 0 profits by producing 0 so if the firm maximises profits at q > 0 profits = pq - c(v,w,q) > 0 so p > AC
- The firm shuts down if price < AC at all levels of output
- The shutdown rule implies that if a profit maximising firms produces q > 0 then price > AC
- Conventionally stated theshutdownrule is: “in the short run a firm should continue to operate if price exceeds average variable costs.” Restated, the rule is that to produce in the short run a firm must earn sufficient revenue to cover its variable costs.
The Output Rule and Marginal Cost
- Profit maximisation at q > 0 implies that marginal revenue = marginal cost
- But marginal revenue = marginal cost does not necessarily imply profit maximisation
- If MR > MC then increasing output q increases profits
- If MR < MC then increasing output q decreases profits
- The Profit MaximizationRulestates that if a firm chooses to maximize its profits, it must choose that level ofoutputwhere Marginal Cost (MC) is equal to Marginal Revenue (MR) and the Marginal Cost curve is rising. In other words, it must produce at a level where MC = MR.
What is Marginal Revenue?
- Perfect competition implies price taking
- Price taking means that nothing the firm can do changes the price
- In particular changing the firm’s output does not change the price
- Price taking implies MR = p = AR (in perfect competition case), does not depend on output
- The price may change for reasons beyond the control of the firm, e.g. an increase in demand
- For a monopoly marginal revenue depends on the firm’s output
- For a firm in an oligopoly MR depends on the firm’s output and the output of other firms
Relationship between MC and AC
- If dAC/dq > 0 same as AC is increasing when MC > AC
- If dAC/dq < 0 same as AC is decreasing when MC < AC
- If dAC/dq = 0 same as AC has a critical point when MC = AC
Profit maximisation by a price taking CRS firm
- The production function q = f(K,L) has constant returns to scale is for all positive numbers m, mf(L,K) = f(mL,mK)
- Under constant returns to scale CRS the optimal ratio of inputs (e.g. the capital labour ratio) depends on w/v
- For given w/v it is the same at all levels of output
- Multiplying inputs by 2 multiplies output by 2
- So it costs twice as much to produce 2 units of output at is costs to procure 1 unit of output
- Total cost is proportional to output
Total cost function from a CRS production function
- As total cost is proportionate to output c(q) = q c(1)
- This implies that MC = AC = c(1)
- MC and AC are equal and do not vary with output
- A firm is a price taker if nothing it can do changes the price p at which it sells
- Profits = pq - total cost = (p-AC) q
- With CRS, AC = MC does not depend on q
- If p > MC increasing q increases profits, there is no profit maximising output
- If p < MC = AC the firms makes losses at all q > 0 so produces 0
- If p = MC = AC the firm makes 0 profit at any q
- p = AC is the only price at which a price taking firm with CRS has a profit maximum at q > 0
Supply by a price taking CRS firm
- MC = AC
- Varies with input prices v and w but not with output
- In some cases the LRMC = LRAC and do not depend on q. This reflects the fact that with this Cobb-Douglas production function, with m > 0, there is constant returns to scale
- Not all CD production functions display CRS, LRMC and LRAC will generally be different from each other and vary with output q
Supply by a firm with CRS and a capacity limit
- Suppose MC and AC are equal and do not vary with output but it is impossible to produce more output than q*
- Profits = pq - total cost = (p-MC)q
- With CRS AC = MC does not depend on q
- If p < MC = AC the firm makes losses at all q > 0 so produces 0
- If p > MC = AC, so increasing q always increases profits, thus output is at its maximum level q*
- If p = AC the firm makes 0 profits at an any q
- MC and AC are equal and do not vary with output but it is impossible to produce more output than q*
Cost curves with DRS
- Under decreasing returns to scale DRS multiplying inputs by 2 multiplies output by less than 2
- So it costs more than twice as much to produce 2 units of output as it costs to produce 1 unit of output, so c(v,w,2q) > 2c(v,w,q)
- More generally with DRS, given input prices if m > 1 so, c(v,w,mq) > m(cv,w,q)
- So AC at output mq = c(v,w,mq)/mq > c(v,w,q)/q = AC output
- AC increases with output
If MC is increasing, p = MC gives profit maximum: intuition
- When q < q1, MC < p, increasing output by 1 unit increases cost by MC and revenue by p
- So long as p* > MC this increases profits
- When q > q1, MC > p*, increasing output by 1 unites increases cost by MC and revenue by p
- As p < MC this decreases profits
Profit maximisation with price taking and a DRS production function
- With DRS MC is increasing and MC > AC
- If p = MC then p > AC so the shutdown rule is satisfied
- The MC curve is the supply curve
- The firm makes profits
Cost curves with IRS
- Under IRS, multiplying inputs by 2 multiplies output by more than 2
- So it costs less than twice as much to produce 2 units of output as it costs to produce 1 unit out output, so c(v,w,2q) < 2c(v,w,q)
- More generally with IRS, given input prices if m > 1
- C(v,w,2q) < 2c(v,w,q)
- So AC at output mq = c(v,w,mq)/mq < c(v,w,q)/q = AC at output q
- AC decreases with output
Total cost function from an IRS production function
- AC decreases as q increases, there are economies of scale
- MC = gradient of tangent < AC = gradient of chord
- MC decreases as q increases
- MC = gradient of tangent < AC = gradient of chord
- MC decreases as q increases
- AC decreases q increases, there are economies of scale
AC and MC from an IRS production function
- MC < AC everywhere
- MC decreases as q increases
- AC decreases as q increases
Price taking with economies of scale at all levels of output is impossible
- Because AC is decreasing either p < AC for all q or p > AC for large q
- Where p < AC for all q, a price taking firm cannot make a profit, the shut down condition is never satisfied
- Where p > AC > MC for large q, there is no profit maximum
- A price taking firm can increase its profits indefinitely
- The firm will expand until it has a large market share and is not a price taker
Costs in an R&D intensive industry
- Total cost = F + cq
- F = R&D cost, opportunity cost before development not an opportunity cost after development
- c = constant marginal cost
- AC = F/q + c decreases at all levels of output
- If a firm has economies of scale at all levels of output, it cannot be a price taker (must be monopoly)
Price taking with economies of scale
• R&D intensive industries with a fixed development cost & constant marginal cost have economies of scale at all levels of output (because initial average cost is SO high, average falls very quickly), must have monopoly power as always incentive for more production
Cost curves and supply with a u-shaped average cost curve
- Often assumed for perfect competition
- For small q there are economies of scale, AC falls
- For large q there are diseconomies of scale, AC rises
Profit maximisation & supply with a u-shaped average cost curve
- MC decreases when q < min point of MC
- And increases when q > min point of MC
- Where AC has it’s minimum it intersects with MC
- Where p < min AC, the firm makes losses at all q > 0, the shut down condition cannot be satisfied at q > 0 so q = 0
- Where p > min AC, the firm can make profits
Long run and short run costs and supply
- Two periods: the planning and production period
- Capital is fixed in the planning period & paid for in the production period
- In the production period capital has no alternative use and cannot be sold, it’s opportunity cost is 0
- Labour is chosen and paid for in the production period
- If the firm knows in the planning period what output and oinput prices will be in the production period it can choose capital optimally and K and L are chosen to minimise total cost c(v,w,q)
- If the firm was uncertain in the planning period about prices in the production period capital may turn out not to be optimal in the production period
- If in the planning period the firm knows output q and input prices w & v in the production period it chooses the cost minimising point on the long run expansion path
- Total inputs (L,K) total cost LRTC = c, when output is q