Chapter 11 - Options Flashcards
what can we consider options as
The option to back away from an unfavorable position. Futures, forwards and all that is an obligation. With options, we dont have this. But naturally, this flexibility has a price. So most of options is about trying to figure out how to price the advantage of being exposed to a certain upside potential, while not having the downside risk.
elaborate on the most important relationship between option prices
Put call parity is essentially about relating the price of a call to the price of a put (with the same strike) by relating them to other financial instruments.
We recognize that a call option has the same “payoff” at expiration as the combination of a long stock and put option.
Because the payoff is the same, we know the cost must be the same. If not, there would be an arbitrage opportunity.
It is temping to say that the price of the call must equal the price of the stock+put, but this doesn’t account for the fact that options work a certain way. A put is a right to sell shares. Since we already have the shares in the long stock+put position, we have all we need. But in the case of the call option, just simply buying the call doesn’t mean that we are “done”. If we want to exercise the call, we only have the right to buy for a certain fixed price. Therefore, we must pay the fixed price. however, since this price is to be paid in the future, we say that the cost is PresentValue(StrikePrice).
Now we can create the equality:
C + PV(K) = P + S
C - P = S - PV(K)
The interpretation of the last line is that if the strike price is very large, it will make the Put more expensive, and the call less expensive, and vice versa.
There is another way to build the relationship between calls and puts. The LHS of the line above can be interpreted as buying a call and selling a put. When we buy a put, we buy the right to acquire an asset, which we will naturally exercise if the asset value is above strike price. When we sell a put, we take on the obligation to buy an asset, should the price of it drop below the strike. As a result, regardless of the asset value, we will end up acquiring the asset for the strike price (assuming strike price is the same for the call and put).
Therefore, this acts as a forward, and we call it synthetic forward.
As a result, and a direct consequence of no arbitrage, we can establish the relationship that the cost of buying a call, less the benefit of selling the put, must be equal to the advantage of buying the asset later, rather than now. We pay the forward price, which we treat as the present value of the forward price, but by paying later we get payed time value of money, which is worth (in today) PV(K), where k is strike price.
The idea here is that the regular forward contract gives us the asset for the forward price. If we could buy a call, sell a put, and use PV(K) to make sure can pay for it, it could be used in arbitrage cases against the actual forward contract.
The whole case is that acquiring assets for a fixed price, which both of these methods do (although the forward price is/can be different from the strike price), they must cost the same. IF they do not cost the same, we can trade arbitrage (same assets, different price). And therefore we can establish the equality relationship:
C-P=PV(forwardprice - K)
what is the more sophisticated put call parity equation
C(K, T) - P(K, T) = e^(-rT)(F_{0,T} - K)
are put call parity referring to american options?
It is actually referring to european
elaborate on put call parity by considering the point where strike equals forward price and go from there
When the strike price is equal to forward price, we have a case where we are ultimately creatign a synthetic forward position to acquire asset. We are looking to acquire it for the forward price, which is usually just the psot price compounded by the risk free rate.
The idea is that doing this with strike equal to forward price is EXACTLY the same as a regular forward contract. Therefore, we expect nothing to be paid to us or us to pay out as a result of it. and since we do it synthetically using options, this means that whatever we pay for the call and whatever we get payed for the put, must equal each other out. This creates a position that is identical to the regular forward.
Think about why this is.
if it was not this way, then it would open up the possibility to make risk free profit. For instance, if the put pay us more than the call cost us, we’d make profit on the synthetic position. This means that we could create it, and at the same time short the forward contract to pay for it.
Same applies for hte other way around.
Now, if we move the strike price away from the forward price, it will shift the balance. For instnace, if we move the strike price below the forward price, it means that the call option is more likely to expire ITM. This is an advantage to us, because we bought the call. However, this is also a disadvantage for the put holders.
And from teh equation, we see that:
P - C = e^(-rT)(F_{0,T} - K)
… a decrease in K makes RHS larger. This makes LHS larger. Both P and C will be adjusted, with P growing smaller and C growing larger.
what can we say about the PV(F_{0,T}) term for options on stocks with dividends
e^(-rT)(F_{0,T}) = S_0 - PV(div)
what is the formula for put call parity when considering options on sticks that pay dividends
C = P + S_0 - PV(div) + e^(-rT)K
what is the formula for put call parity whne considering options on indices that have continuously compounded dividends
recall that dividends for indices are continuouslly re-invested, which will result in a new number of shares rather than cash.
If we are payed ∂ anually, we get:
e^(∂T) new number of shares.
This typically measn that if we invest S_0e^(-∂T) we have a tailed position that gets us 1 share at the end of the year.
For the options pricing, we arrive at:
C = P + S_0 e^(-∂T) - e^(-rT)K
what can we say about hte difference between the call and put?
Why is the price of a call for ATM always larger than price of PUT AMT?
It is equal to the itnerest rate of holding cash until expiration. If we lock in 50 bucks, we have to pay interest on this.
This is why the call is more expensive. We have to pay interest on the fact that we are deferring payment.
elaborate on the statement that calls are more worth because upside is ulimited while this is not the case for puts
while true, the statement is false. If calls are more expensive, it is because of the time value of money.
for the ATM options, this is easy to understand. We could pay now, or later. Since we purchase option, we pay later. And therefore, we pay the time value of money.
what can we say about american vs european options
since the american options have more flexibility, they can never be worth less than the their european counterpart.
can european call options be negative?
no, because they need not be exercised.t
what is the maximum value of a european call option?
The stock price itself. The worst case scenario is that we imply pay for the stock.
elaborate on early exercise
American call options on non-dividend paying stocks should never be exercised early becasue of the time value of money.
explian this notation:
C(S, Q, T-t)
the call price when considering some asset S that we are giving away in exchange for asset Q when there is T-t time left.
This is a converntion that is abstract, but represent two assets that are exchanged. Typically for financial options, S is the stock price while Q is the strike price. Thus, it represent how we receive S while giving up Q.
For call options, the payoff at the point in time when there is 0 time left:
C(S_T, Q_T, 0) = maximum(S_T - Q_T, 0)
Opposiute for the put.
what is the most general way of stating the put call parity equaiton that we use
C(S_t, Q_t, T-t) - P(S_t, Q_t, T-t) = F^P_{t, T}(S) - F^P_{t,T}(Q)
We are buying a call, which entails us receiving S_t in exchange for Q_t. we sell a put, which entail us buying Q_t in exchange for S_t.
The prepaid forward price of the assets represent their values when deferring payment, including all kinds of dividends etc.
discuss the distinction between calls and puts
Calls and puts are determined on what we choose to label as the asset we buy, and the asset we sell.
If we buy a call regular call, we exchange our cash to receive stock. but from the perspective of someone who is looking to purchase cash, this option is a put. Why? because the derivative increase in value if the strike asset is worth more than the regular asset.
For us, the option is worth more if the regular asset is increasing in value relative to the strike asset.
But if we look from the perspective of the strike asset, it is the other way around.
For instance, if the regular asset is a house, and the strike asset is a car: usually, we’d consider this a call, and say that if the house is worth more than the car, we earn a profit.
But, if we consider it the other way around, and we want to acquire the car for the house, we will make money if the value of the house drop relative to the car. So it is sort of determined on what we label as the strike asset.
give the proof of why early exercise on non-dividend paying american call option is never beneficial
we use the original parity equaiton:
This is for european options.
C(S_t, K, T-t) - P(S_t, K, T-t) = PV(F_{t,T}) - PV(K)
re-arranging we get:
C(S_t, K, T-t) = P(S_t, K, T-t) + S_t - e^(-r(T-t))K
C(S_t, K, T-t) = P(S_t, K, T-t) + S_t - K + K(1 - e^(-r(T-t)))
Now we can isolate S_t - K. We basically have that the value of the put, which can never be negative, plus K(1-e^(-r(ttt))), which can never be negative since exponent is negative, we can conclude that the CALL is always greater than the (S_t - K), which represent the exercise value.
Then we also know that the american value must be greater than the european. Therefore, the american call option is never good to exercise early either.
in the result of the proof of why early exervise is not beneficial, we decompose the price of a call option into 3 parts. Elaborate on these
We have the exervise value, S_t - K.
Then we have the implicit put protection that protects us from downside movement.
Thirdly, we have the time value of money. This is listed as K(1-e^(-r(T-t)))
Therefore, by exercising early, we throw away the protection AND we accelerate the payment by neglecting that we have time value.
what can we say is the short conclusion regarding the early exercise of american call options?
We should never see them sell for less than S_t - K
give the formula for put call paritty in the case of dividnds.
Can we say that early exercise is stil never beneficial?
We end up with:
C(S_t, K, T-t) = P(S_t, K, T-t) + S_t - PV(div) - PV(K),
where the present values are in regards to time t, of course.
The case now is that there may be cases where the dividends are greater than the interest we’d get from deferring payment. The thing is that we have to exercise if we want the dividends, so simply selling the option further is no bueno as the new buyer would have to exercise as well if he want the dividends.
Recall what we did for the no dividend case. We had only positive terms, except for (S_t - K). It is easy to conclude that the price of the call therefore would always be larger than this difference, which makes is never beneficial to exercise early.
However, now we do have a negative component in the dividends.
We can conclude by saying that if early exercise is optimal as a result of the dividnesxd, we should wait as long as possible, which is the day before ex-dividend date to do so.
elaborate on early exercise for puts
THe case for puts is different than for options. Suppose the firm’s share goes to 0.
if we do not exercise, we will end up with PV(K), taken relative to timestep t.
However, if we exercise immediately, we get K. Why would we want this?
because if the interest rate is positive, we would get K > PV(K).
can parity give a condition where we will early exercise for puts?
no. The case is that we can not say whether we should or shouldnt early exercise.
For calls, the case is simple as we could rule out early exercise. For puts, this is not the case. We cannot say that we should early exercise. We can only say that parity cannot rule it out.
generally speaking, what can we say is a neceassry condition for early exercise?
the necessary condition is that we want something now, ratehr than later. For stock returns without dividneds, there is no reason to have this wish. This is why calls never should be exercised early.
BUT: If there are dividends, we may want them more than we want the risk free return. In such case, there may be a case to exercise early.