CFAI 3- Economics Flashcards
theory of the consumer
deals with consumption (the demand for goods and services) by utility-maximizing individuals (i.e., individuals who make decisions that maximize the satisfaction received from present and future consumption).
theory of the firm
deals with the supply of goods and services by profit-maximizing firms. The theory of the consumer and the theory of the firm are important because they help us understand the foundations of demand and supply. Subsequent readings will focus on the theory of the consumer and the theory of the firm.
Os mercados podem dividir-se em :
Factor Markets are markets for the purchase and sale of factors of production. In capitalist private enterprise economies, households own the factors of production (the land, labor, physical capital, and materials used in production)
Good Markets are markets for the output of production. From an economics perspective, firms, which ultimately are owned by individuals either singly or in some corporate form, are organizations that buy the services of those factors. Firms then transform those services into intermediate or final goods and services.
If, at a given quantity, the highest price that buyers are willing to pay is equal to the lowest price that sellers are willing to accept
the quantity is at equilibrium
when the quantity that buyers are willing and able to purchase at a given price is just equal to the quantity that sellers are willing to offer at that same price, we say the market has discovered ….
the equilibrium price
Qdx=f(Px,I,Py,…)
o que representam as variáveis?
where Qdx
represents the quantity demanded of some good X (such as per household demand for gasoline in gallons per week), Px is the price per unit of good X (such as $ per gallon), I is consumers’ income (as in $1,000s per household annually), and Py is the price of another good, Y. (There can be many other goods, not just one, and they can be complements or substitutes.) Equation 1 may be read, “Quantity demanded of good X depends on (is a function of) the price of good X, consumers’ income, the price of good Y, and so on.”
Qdx=8.4−0.4Px+0.06I−0.01Py
Interpretar a função, sendo que Px é o preço da gasolina, Py é o preço do carro em milhares e I é o income anual em milhares
The signs of the coefficients on gasoline price (negative) and consumer’s income (positive) are intuitive, reflecting, respectively, an inverse and a positive relationship between those variables and quantity of gasoline consumed. The negative sign on average automobile price may indicate that if automobiles go up in price, fewer will be purchased and driven; hence less gasoline will be consumed. As will be discussed later, such a relationship would indicate that gasoline and automobiles have a negative cross-price elasticity of demand and are thus complements.
If we pretend to know how does the quantity demanded responds to one variable we have to fix the other variables with a value so we can study the function.
Qdx=8.4−0.4Px+0.06(50)−0.01(20)=11.2−0.4Px
Notice that income and the price of automobiles are not ignored; they are simply held constant, and they are “collected” in the new constant term, 11.2. Notice also that we can rearrange Equation 3, solving for Px in terms of Qx. This operation is called “inverting the demand function,” and gives us Equation 4. (You should be able to perform this algebraic exercise to verify the result.)
Equation (4)
Px=28−2.5Qx
Equation 4, which gives the per-gallon price of gasoline as a function of gasoline consumed per week, is referred to as the inverse demand function. We need to restrict Qx in Equation 4 to be less than or equal to 11.2 so price is not negative. Henceforward we assume that the reader can work out similar needed qualifications to the valid application of equations. The graph of the inverse demand function is called the demand curve, and is shown in
Supply Function and the Supply Curve
Qsx=f(Px,W,…)
where Qsx
is the quantity supplied of some good X, such as gasoline, Px is the price per unit of good X, and W is the wage rate of labor in, say, dollars per hour. It would be read, “The quantity supplied of good X depends on (is a function of) the price of X (its “own” price), the wage rate paid to labor, etc.”
Equation (8)
Qsx=−175+250Px−5W
Notice that this supply function says that for every increase in price of $1, this seller would be willing to supply an additional 250 units of the good. Additionally, for every $1 increase in wage rate that it must pay its laborers, this seller would experience an increase in marginal cost and would be willing to supply five fewer units of the good.
We might be interested in the relationship between only two of these variables, price and quantity supplied. Just as we did in the case of the demand function, we use the assumption of ceteris paribus and hold everything except own-price and quantity constant. In our example, we accomplish this by setting W to some value, say, $15. The result is Equation 9:
Equation (9)
Qsx=−175+250Px−5(15)=−250+250Px
(Institute 10)
Institute, CFA. 2015 CFA Level I Volume 2 Economics. Wiley Global Finance, 2014-07-14. VitalBook file.
A citação disponibilizada é um exemplo. Verifique a exactidão de cada citação antes de utilizar.
Determine the inverse supply function for an individual seller.
Ou inverse demand function
Quando pede a função inversa devemos resolver uma função do tipo
Qsx=−175+250Px−5W
ou
Qdx
em função do tempo com os outros elementos fixados.
o que nos dá o slope na curva de supply e demmand?
a slope de uma função preço/quantidade dá a variação do preço por cada unidade de diferença.
If the supply curve has negative slope like the demand curve we can say that…
Notice that in “Panel A” both demand (D) and supply (S) are negatively sloped, but S is steeper and intersects D from above. In this case, if price is above equilibrium, there will be excess supply and the market mechanism will adjust price downward toward equilibrium. In Panel B, D is steeper, which results in S intersecting D from below. In this case, at a price above equilibrium there will be excess demand, and the market mechanism will dictate that price should rise, thus leading away from equilibrium. This equilibrium would be considered unstable. If price were accidentally displayed above the equilibrium price, the mechanism would not cause price to converge to that equilibrium, but instead to soar above it because there would be excess demand at that price. In contrast, if price were accidentally displayed below equilibrium, the mechanism would force price even further below equilibrium because there would be excess supply.
Como é que se criam bolhas numa ótica de curva de supply and demand?
As a simple approach to understanding bubbles, consider a case in which buyers and sellers base their expectations of future prices on the rate of change of current prices: if price rises, they take that as a sign that price will rise even further. Under these circumstances, if buyers see an increase in price today, they might actually shift the demand curve to the right, desiring to buy more at each price today because they expect to have to pay more in the future. Alternately, if sellers see an increase in today’s price as evidence that price will be even higher in the future, they are reluctant to sell today as they hold out for higher prices tomorrow, and that would shift the supply curve to the left. With a rightward shift in demand and a leftward shift in supply, buyers’ and sellers’ expectations about price are confirmed and the process begins again. This scenario could result in a bubble that would inflate until someone decides that such high prices can no longer be sustained. The bubble bursts and price plunges.
Diferença entre:
common value auction
private value auction
common value auction in which there is some actual common value that will ultimately be revealed after the auction is settled. Prior to the auction’s settlement, however, bidders must estimate that true value. An example of a common value auction would be bidding on a jar containing many coins. Each bidder could estimate the value; but until someone buys the jar and actually counts the coins, no one knows with certainty the true value. In the second case, called a private value auction, each buyer places a subjective value on the item, and in general their values differ. An example might be an auction for a unique piece of art that buyers are hoping to purchase for their own personal enjoyment, not primarily as an investment to be sold later.
Outros tipos de Leilões:
Perhaps the most familiar auction mechanism is the ascending price auction
in which an auctioneer is selling a single item in a face-to-face arena where potential buyers openly reveal their willingness to buy the good at prices that are called out by an auctioneer. The auctioneer begins at a low price and easily elicits nods from buyers. He then raises the price incrementally. In a common value auction, buyers can sometimes learn something about the true value of the item being auctioned from observing other bidders. Ultimately bidders with different maximum amounts they are willing to pay for the item, called reservation prices, begin to drop out of the bidding as price rises above their respective reservation prices.4 Finally, only one bidder is left (who has outbid the bidder with the second highest valuation) and the item is sold to that bidder for his bid price.
Sometimes sellers offer a common value item, such as an oil or timber lease, in a sealed bid auction. In this case, bids are elicited from potential buyers, but there is no ability to observe bids by other buyers until the auction has ended.
In the first price sealed bid auction,
the envelopes containing bids are opened simultaneously and the item is sold to the highest bidder for the actual bid price. Consider an oil lease being auctioned by the government. The highest bidder will pay his bid price but does not know with certainty the profitability of the asset on which he is bidding. The profits that are ultimately realized will be learned only after a successful bidder buys and exploits the asset. Bidders each have some expected value they place on the oil lease, and those values can vary among bidders. Typically, some overly optimistic bidders will value the asset higher than its ultimate realizable value, and they might submit bids above that true value. Because the highest bidder wins the auction and must pay his full bid price, he may find that he has fallen prey to the winner’s curse of having bid more than the ultimate value of the asset. The “winner” in this case will lose money because he has paid more than the value of the asset being auctioned. In recognition of the possibility of being overly optimistic, bidders might bid very conservatively below their expectation of the true value. If all bidders react in this way, the seller might end up with a low sale price.
If the item being auctioned is a private value item, then there is no danger of the winner’s curse (no one would bid more than their own true valuation). But bidders try to guess the reservation prices of other bidders, so the most successful winning bidder would bid a price just above the reservation price of the second-highest bidder. This bid will be below the true reservation price of the highest bidder, resulting in a “bargain” for the highest bidder. To induce each bidder to reveal their true reservation price, sellers can use the second price sealed bid mechanism (also known as a Vickery auction). In this mechanism, the bids are submitted in sealed envelopes and opened simultaneously. The winning buyer is the one who submitted the highest bid, but the price she pays is not equal to her own bid. She pays a price equal to the second-highest bid. The optimal strategy for any bidder in such an auction is to bid her actual reservation price, so the second price sealed bid auction induces buyers to reveal their true valuation of the item. It is also true that if the bidding increments are small, the second price sealed bid auction will yield the same ultimate price as the ascending price auction.
Yet another type of auction is called a descending price auction or Dutch auction in which the auctioneer begins at a very high price—a price so high that no bidder is believed to be willing to pay it.5 The auctioneer then lowers the called price in increments until there is a willing buyer of the item being sold. If there are many bidders, each with a different reservation price and a unit demand, then each has a perfectly vertical demand curve at one unit and a height equal to his reservation price. For example, suppose the highest reservation price is equal to $100. That person would be willing to buy one unit of the good at a price no higher than $100. Suppose each subsequent bidder also has a unit demand and a reservation price that falls, respectively, in increments of $1. The market demand curve would be a negatively sloped step function; that is, it would look like a stair step, with the width of each step being one unit and the height of each step being $1 lower than the preceding step. For example, at a price equal to $90, 11 people would be willing to buy one unit of the good. If the price were to fall to $89, then the quantity demanded would be 12, and so on.
consumer surplus
To get an intuitive feel for this concept, consider the last thing you purchased. Maybe it was a cup of coffee, a new pair of shoes, or a new car. Whatever it was, think of how much you actually paid for it. Now contrast that price with the maximum amount you would have been willing to pay for it instead of going without it altogether. If those two numbers are different, we say you received some consumer surplus from your purchase. You received a “bargain” because you were willing to pay more than you had to pay.
Perceber como identificar o consumer surplus dentro da linha de procura
Total Surplus, como é que podemos ver pelas curvas de procura e oferta se é o produtor ou o consumidor que mais beneficia do total surplus?
QUando é maximizado?
Tudo depende da inclinação da curva da procura e da oferta, quanto mais inclinada for a curva maior é a parcela que a entidade à qual se refere a curva adquire do total surplus.
É maximizado quando estamos no preço de equilibrio.
No mercado em que o preço está em equilíbrio este pode dizer-se que é
o custo marginal da unidade do produto.
Price Ceiling e Price Floor, como funcionam e quais os problemas?
Como afetam os impostos aplicados ao consumidor e ao produtor?
Os Price Ceiling, Price Floor e impostos criam Deadweight Loss é perdido total surplus.
Quando os impostos incidem sobre o vendedor p.e. como é que calculamos o impacto e quem sai mais afetado?
Para calcular o impacto tempos que ver a variação do preço no lado do Vendedor e calcular o novo preço de equilibrio. Com esse preço de equilibrio podemos observar qual a parcela que é imputada ao comprador Peq novo-Peq antigo. Ao vendedor é imputado o remanescente.
A curva com maior inclinação é a que tem o maior surplus, mas também é a que sofre o maior impacto no caso de aumento de impostos. Na teoria é indiferente em quem é imputada a taxa.
No caso de a taxa ser aplicada sobre os vendedores devemos somar a taxa à intercepção na formula visto que os vendedores agora querem mais X para vender.
No caso da taxa ser aplicada aos compradores devemos subtrair a taxa na fórmula porque agora os compradores querem um produto X mais barato visto que vão pagar a taxa.
O que é o conceito de elasticidade nas curvas de procura e oferta?
Que conclusões podemos tirar de diferntes valores de Elasticidade?
Recall that when we introduced the concept of a demand function with Equation 1 earlier, we were simply theorizing that quantity demanded of some good, such as gasoline, is dependent on several other variables, one of which is the price of gasoline itself. We referred to the law of demand that simply states the inverse relationship between the quantity demanded and the price. Although that observation is useful, we might want to dig a little deeper and ask, Just how sensitive is quantity demanded to changes in the price of gasoline? Is it highly sensitive, so that a very small rise in price is associated with an enormous fall in quantity, or is the sensitivity only minimal? It might be helpful if we had a convenient measure of this sensitivity.
Exemplo da elasticidade do preço na curva da procura:
Edpx=%ΔQdx%ΔPx
elasticidade é a variação da quantidade procurada de um ativo devido à variação do seu preço, neste caso. (ambos em percentagem)
1) If Ep > 1, Demand is elastic. The percentage change in price will produce a greater percentage in quantity demanded. If the price goes up, then total revenues will go down. If the price goes down, then total revenues willincrease.
2) If Ep
Numa reta de procura a procura é elástica…. inelástica… e unitáriamente elástica
Uma recta de procura vertical tem ….
Uma recta de procura horizontal tem …
acima do ponto médio, abaixo do ponto médio e no ponto médio.
vertical… tem 0 elasticidade perfectly inelastic
Horizontal tem elasticidade infinita é perfeitamente elástica.
A procura é menos elástica quanto mais dificil for arranjar um substituto para o produto em questão.
For a market, the total expenditure by buyers becomes the total revenue to sellers in that market. It follows, then, that if market demand is elastic, a fall in price will result in an increase in total revenue to sellers as a whole, and if demand is inelastic, a fall in price will result in a decrease in total revenue to sellers. Clearly, if the demand faced by any given seller were inelastic at the current price, that seller could increase revenue by increasing its price. Moreover, because demand is negatively sloped, the increase in price would decrease total units sold, which would almost certainly decrease total cost. So no one-product seller would ever knowingly choose to set price in the inelastic range of its demand.
income elasticity can be negative, positive, or zero
why? não devia ser sempre positiva?
Any good with a positive income of elasticity of demand is said to be a normal good. Luxury goods have high income elasticity (greater than one). The proportionate amount of spending for those goods will go up as incomes increase.
The amount spent on some goods decrease as incomes goes up. Such goods are referred to as inferior goods. Examples of inferior goods include margarine (inferior to butter) and bus travel (inferior to owning a vehicle).
Elasticity of demand Cross-price
Substitutes and complements
Cross elasticity of demand relates the percentage change in quantity demanded of a good to the percentage change in price of a substitute or complementary good. Examples of complementary goods would include peanut butter and jelly, and large SUVs and gasoline. The cross elasticity of demand will be positive for a substitute, and negative for a complement; i.e. demand for a substitute (complement) will go up (down), if the price of the substitute (complement) goes up.
Substitutes are defined empirically. If the cross-price elasticity of two goods is positive, they are substitutes, irrespective of whether someone would consider them “similar.”
For substitute goods, an increase in the price of one good would shift the demand curve for the other good upward and to the right. For complements, however, the impact is in the other direction: When the price of one good rises, the quantity demanded of the other good shifts downward and to the left.
Consumer Theory
Consumer choice theory begins with a fundamental model of how consumer preferences and tastes might be represented. It explores consumers’ willingness to trade off between two goods (or two baskets of goods), both of which the consumer finds beneficial. Consumer choice theory then recognizes that to consume a set of goods and services, consumers must purchase them at given market prices and with a limited income. In effect, consumer choice theory first models what the consumer would like to consume, and then it examines what the consumer can consume with limited income. Finally, by superimposing what the consumer would like to do onto what the consumer can do, we arrive at a model of what the consumer would do under various circumstances. Then by changing prices and income, the model develops consumer demand as a logical extension of consumer choice theory.
Axioms of the Theory of Consumer Choice
Quais são e o que significam? 3
Complete Preferences
Given this understanding of consumption bundles, the first assumption we make about a given consumer’s preferences is simply that she is able to make a comparison between any two possible bundles. That is, given bundles A and B, she must be able to say either that she prefers A to B, or she prefers B to A, or she is indifferent between the two. This is the assumption of complete preferences
Transitive Preferences
Second, we assume that when comparing any three distinct bundles, A, B, and C, if A is preferred to B, and simultaneously B is preferred to C, then it must be true that A is preferred to C. This assumption is referred to as the assumption of transitive preferences
Non Satiation
Finally, we usually assume that in at least one of the goods, the consumer could never have so much that she would refuse any more, even if it were free. This assumption is sometimes referred to as the “more is better” assumption or the assumption of non-satiation
.