1.4 Price change and Welfare Flashcards

1
Q

From 1.1-1.3 what have we explored?

A

In 1.1 - 1.3 we explored how to find uncompensated demand, compensated
demand and the expenditure function

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

What will we do today?

A

examine the welfare effects of price changes

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

What are price indices?

A

A price index is a number whose movement reflects movement in the average level of prices

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

In the economy we know prices are changing at different weights so what do we want?

A

we want a weighted average of price changes, due to this votality of price. This will be a price index

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

What are the different price indicies in the uk?

A

CPI ( now the standard)
CPIH ( Consumer price index including owner occupiers housing costs)
RPI ( retail price index)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

What is CPI?

A

Measures the change in the cost of a representative basket of goods and services bought by households
• Interpreted as a measure of how the cost of the standard of living is changing.
Official inflation target is 2%
Compares baskets quarterly, annually.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

What is Consumer Prices Index including owner occupiers’ housing costs (CPIH)

A

Extends CPI to include a measure of the costs associated with owning, maintaining and living in one’s own home.
• OOH costs and Council Tax are significant expenses for many households

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

What is CPI an example of?

A

A base weighted index. ( It has a base year, were we draw comparisons from.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

Define a base-weighted price index

A

A weighted average of prices or quantities, where the weights used are the quantities or the prices of the base period.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

We are going to show the base weighted price index mathematically?
How do we show a representative consumer basket of n goods at date A and prices of the goods at date A.

A
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Now show the mathematically representation of the prices when we look a year late and then show the base weighted price index?

A

Its essentiallty prices of same bundle at later date/prices of bundle at earlier date.
We are assuming the bundle is fixed, we are going focusing on prices.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

What are some critiques of CPI?

A

1) The CPI does not take into account the real possibility that consumers would substitute among commodities because of changes in relative prices (cheaper product you buy more) . Substitution bias. Hence it overstates the inflation rate.
2) No representative consumer, there are different segments of consumer reflecting different basket of goods.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q
If income changes in line with
the base weighted price index, then:
A. Consumers are neither better off nor
worse off
B. Consumers cannot be worse off, but
may be better off
C. Consumers cannot be better off, but
may be worse off
D. Consumers will definitely be better off
A

B

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q
If income changes in line with
the base weighted price index,
then:
A. Consumers are neither better off nor
worse off
B. Consumers cannot be worse off, but
may be better off
C. Consumers cannot be better off, but
may be worse off
D. Consumers will definitely be better off

We are going to analyse why b is the answer. So suppose there are 2 goods, how does the CPI base weighted price index look like?

A
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q
If income changes in line with
the base weighted price index,
then:
A. Consumers are neither better off nor
worse off
B. Consumers cannot be worse off, but
may be better off
C. Consumers cannot be better off, but
may be worse off
D. Consumers will definitely be better off

We are going to analyse why b is the answer. Now show the prices and bundle consumers pick before changes in price and after price change and the utlitiy they get?

A
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

What does it mean if income changes at the same rate as the base weighted priced index

A

This means you can afford the original basket but wil lyou prefer the original basket?
It depends on what happens to prices individually( relative prices, subsistution effect) so the bundle is affordable but not optimal.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
17
Q

Now what is subsitution bias?

A

if consumers change their purchasing behavior in response to relative price changes. (• If relative prices p1/p2(increase in price of good 1 > increase in price of good 2) change and substitution is possible then the
consumer is better off!)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
18
Q

If income increases at the same rate as the base weighted price index

A

then the consumer cannot be worse off

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
19
Q

To show why a consumer cannot be worse off if income changes at the same rate as the base weighted price index, draw the original budget line and graph and show optimal point?
1) Construct the budget line, with 2 goods?

A
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
20
Q

PART 2) To show why a consumer cannot be worse off if income changes at the same rate as the base weighted price index,
Now suppose prices change but also income at the same rate so P1bX1a + P2bX2a =m. Lets imagine the price of good 1 rose higher than good 2 e.g. good 1 is fuel and it rose by 4% and good 2 rose by 2% but average so CPI went up by 3% , and income goes up by 3%. Show what happens to budget line. What what does it show about being worse off?

A

The budget line becomes steeper as prices of both goods have increased ( become steeper).
It still goes through bundle A because you can still afford (x1A,x2A). Thus cannot be worseoff.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
21
Q

Will the consumer pick bundle A, if he/she income rises at the same ratio as CPI (3%) increases, and he negotiates a 3% increase at work?
Draw where optimal consumption would be and explain what it shows about CPI?

A

This will show for individuals, CPI basket of goods are not constant, here substation effects causes you to buy the cheaper thing (x2). Thus as we saw last week to get same utility, your overall inflation is <3% but CPI overstate it to 3%.( due to subsitution effects because of changes in relative price, CPI is an overestimate, as the bundle of goods are fixed, but actually they change)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
22
Q

Are consumers always better off when there is an iincrease in income in line with an increase in CPI? ( remember relative prices change, 1 is the same as the other)

A

No is the answer, it depends whether or not there is a subsitution effect of not. so perfect complements there will be no change in allocation.
If PC if income rises higher than CPI or just rises, then they will be better off.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
23
Q

What happens if prices rise ( e.g. good 1 and 2 rise by 3% at the same rate as income so 3%?

A

The budget line stats the same, this is because it is homogeneous to degree 0
or
The BL intercepts are m/p1 and m/p2 so an increase in both as no change BlA = BLb ( consumers are no better off or worse off)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
24
Q

So in summary we line wages, income etc to inflation to get away from harmful effects of inflation ( CPI increases) but whats the problem of this use the example previously?

A

Subsitution bias can make people better off e.g. if you give a rise in income, to someone who experiences a relative price change with 3% overall( price changes different for the 2 goods,) they might substitute away and be better off. THUS THERE IS OVER COMPENSATION.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
25
Q

Suppose you wanted to compensate the person for inflation ( CPI increases), but not over compensate them ( make them as well off as before, but go on a higher indifference curve– so less money), how would we do this?

A

By using something called the expenditure function price index.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
26
Q

What is the expenditure function E(p1,p2,u) again?

A

is the minimum amount of money you have to spend to get utility u with prices p1 and p2.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
27
Q

How would the expenditure function price index work and show the mathematically representation of it?

A

So you keep utility constant and find the minimum expenditure of achieving that utility b4 and after the price change. e.g. if the minimum expenditure needed UA in august 2020 was 100, then the minimum expenditure needed to get UA in 2021 is £102, thats a 2% rise and thats exactly how much extra money you have to give to compensate them, keeping utlity constant.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
28
Q

How would we show the expenditure function price index on a diagram? Does the budget line go through bundle A?

A

1) The new budget line doesn’t go through bundle A, as we are not trying to compensate the individual through bundle A.
2) We have IC of an individual Ua, we know prices initially and we are trying to minimise the cost of achieving UA, so we get bundle A.
3) Relative prices change ( e.g. good 1 increases by 4% and good 2 2% so overall =3% cpi), now we find what is the minimum to achieve UA now. We find new bundle C.
4) The ratio of the y intercepts is the expenditure price index

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
29
Q

What would it mean if income was to go up at the same rate as the expenditure function price index and compare with CPI?

A

Then people will be as well off as before and after inflation. But you wouldn’t be overcompensating or undercompensating them. If this happens with CPI the consumer is possibly better off.( subsitution bias)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
30
Q

Now put it all together the base weighted price index vs expenditure function price index. If price rises e.g. good 1 rises by 4% and good 2 rises by 2% so cpi average increase is 3% and you compensate them with CPI giving 3% increase in income but with Expenditure function price index you compensate using the exact amount of the proportion using the expenditure function show that on a graph?

A

1) August 2020 we are at bundle A, if we compensate people at original bundle, they subisutute and go to a higher IC with utility Ub
2) . If we the expenditure price index, the consumer is at bundle c ( less money

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
31
Q

What are problems with the expenditure function price index ( BTW this is not a real thing)?

A

1) Requires knowledge of the expenditure function( we need to know preferences.)
2) The expenditure function is derived from a utility function ( what is a representative utility function of society.)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
32
Q

EXAM QUESTION Margaret’s consumption reflects the weights of the Consumer Price Index (CPI). If the inflation rate is 3% (as measured by the CPI) and Margaret’s income increases by 3%, can she ever be worse off? What determines if she will be better off?

A

You can draw a diagram
1) Margaret’s consumption is exactly the one used to compute the CPI so she is still able to afford her initial consumption bundle if she receives an income increase of 3%. As the original bundle she was consuming is still available to her, she can never be worse off.
She might be better off if not all items in the basket considered have a higher price (so relative price changes) and she can substitute to cheaper goods (substitution bias)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
33
Q

(c) Alex lives in London and has unusual tastes in consumer goods. His income increases by 3%, in line with the Consumer Price Index. Could he be worse off?

A

Alex can be worse off. He may not be consuming the same goods as those considered in the computation for the CPI. This means that while his income increases in line with the CPI, his previous bundle of consumption might have a much higher price now and he may not be able to afford it. If this is the case Alex will be worse off even though he now earns more. Because we don’t know anything about those prices we cannot determine whether he will be better off, equally well off or worse off.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
34
Q

Now we are going to measure the impact of price changes on consumer welfare in monetary terms? 1) Why monetary terms and 2) what Concepts will we look at?

A

1) We want to compensate people from impact of policies e.g. tax, this especially affects low income familiies.
2) We will look at Compensation variation, Equivalent variation developed by hicks and its relationship to consumer surplus.

35
Q

Lets look at consumer surplus first, do 2 things 1) show on an indifference map an increase in price of good 1 from p1a to p1b ( just showing the overall change 2) translate this on an uncompensated demand curve diagram? ASSUME BOTH GOODS ARE NORMAL GOODS. Explain both diagrams and what happens when you move long the demand curve. Where is the CS?

A

1) Indifference map: originally consumer optimises his ultiity given prices and income, but then price of good 1 increases so the budget line pivots inwards, meaning we cant afford same bundle. As both goods are normal we buy less of both goods overall, so we get lower levels of utlitiy.
2) Bundle B represents a higher price and lower quantity and different utlitiy level. in relation to A involves a higher quantity and a lower price, hence we can translate this to the demand curve.
3) As we move along the uncompensated demand curve the utlitiy is changing ( Bundle A has a higher utlity than B)
Consumer surplus is the blue area.

36
Q

If i could calculate the blue area and pay it back to consumers will they be as well of as they began ( i.e. get to the indifference curve A)?

A

No they will not and we will see why later.

37
Q

What is compensating variation?

A

How much do we have to increase/decrease the consumer’s income if we want their utility to remain the same after a change in market prices?
KEY HERE IS THAT WE ARE NOT TRYINH TO MAKE THEM BETTER OFF OR WORSE OFF.

38
Q

What is compensating variation when price increase for good 1 and what about when it decreases?

A

Price decrease : how much money a consumer would be willing to give up AFTER a reduction in prices to be just as well off as BEFORE the price change.
Price increase: CV is the minimum amount the consumer would need
AFTER a price increase to be as well off as BEFORE the price increase

39
Q

How would we show CV on a indifference map diagram? So lets say the price increases from p1A to P1B for good 1? what is the movement from A. to B the subsitution effect, there is a change in compensated demand.

A

1) Price increases from P1A to p1b, thus budget line pivots inwards, leading to point B,( lower utility)
2) The consumer then needs to get income added back to push them back to the original level of utility, so we draw a parallel line or increase income line till it is tangent to the original indifference curve, as we know we have compensated them. ( IT doesn’t go through A) the consumer will end up at B.

40
Q

What are are the intercepts? and how does this give us an estimate of EV.

A

1) The intercept of the original budget line is the minimum expenditure needed to achieve utility uA ( expenditure function)/p2 as its quantities .
2) The intercept of new compensated budget line is the minimum expenditure needed to achieve uA at the new prices/p2 as its quantities.
The difference in the y axis is the compensated variation CV/p2
so E( p1b,p2b,ub)-E(p1a,p2a,ua)

41
Q

Integrating over 2 limits gives you what?

A

The area under a curve

42
Q

Recall the shephards lemma and use the fact to find out what happens when we integrate?

A

1) If we partially differentiate the expenditure function with respect to price of good 1 we can get the the compensated demand for h1.
2) If we integrate the h1 function across 2 price limits p1A and p1B, you get the difference of the 2 y intercepts which is the compensating variation.

43
Q

Now show compensated demand on a demand curve for good 1?

A

1) Bundle B represents a higher price and less quantity but same utility, so we illustrate that in respect to A, the key here is that the utlitiy is not changing here on the compensated demand curve.

44
Q

Is the area under the curve for compensating variation the same as CS, which is more accurate?

A

when we looked at CS we looked at area under uncompensated demand curve utility was changing for different prices and quantity, here utility is constant along the demand curve.
CV is more precise to find out the money needed to compensate consumers for a price change.

45
Q

What is equivalent Variation?

A

EV is the amount of money that needs to be taken away
from the consumer without changing prices has
the same effect on utility as the price change

46
Q

What is EV when price increases for good 1 and decreases?

A

Price fall: the increase in income that would give the consumer the same additional utility that would happen if a price did fall.
Price increase: EV would be the amount of income that would be taken
away to lower the consumer’s utility to the level that would happen if the change had occurred during a price change.

47
Q

How do you draw EV on an indifference diagram?

A

1) We are at bundle A with utility UA, the prices of good 1 rises, budget line pivots inwards, thus the consumer reoptimises at bundle B, and achieves utility UB.
2) Now we would have to show an income reduction that would have been as bad as a price increase.
3) so you do a parallel shift from the original budget line until you get tangent to the new indifference curve and you get bundle C.
4) B to C represents the change in compensated demand along the utility curve

48
Q

What can EV be used for?

A

If there is say a carbon tax, this may price rise for good 1, so we might want to do an EV to find how much income is reduced for households.

49
Q

What are the y intercepts

A

The higher intercept is the minimum expenditure needed to achieve UB at new prices
The lower intercept is the minimum expenditure needed to achieve THE same utility but at original prices.
The gab between these is EV/P2 so times by P2 and you get EV ( change in income that would be as bad as a price change.

50
Q

Draw the EV on a demand diagram?

Remember its in relationship to that?

A

B and C not A

51
Q

Remember in an exam question the downward sloping budget lines and convex to the origin IC’s only correspond to what type of preferences

A

Cobb-douglas, be careful when looking at the different types of preferences.

52
Q

Now we are going to put everything together Consumer surplus, CV and EV on a demand curve from an indifference map to demand curve, but so what are the summarised steps to do this, if we assume both goods are normal goods?

A

1) we show first CS
2) CV
3) then EV.

53
Q

First of all draw CV AND EV on an indifference map and explain it again, assuming prices went up for good 1 and it is CB preferences.

A

1) Price increase for good 1, budget line pivots in and we get to a new bundle point C, which is a higher price and lower quantity bundle with a lower utility.
2) We want to compensate the consumer back to his original utility, but not make him better off or worse off, so draw a fake budget line up the original indifference curve to a new bundle B parallel to C.
3) Now with EV, we want to calculate the amount of money we have to take away that would be as bad as a tax. ( from the original budget line, draw a fake budget line downwards until its tangent to the new indifference curve to get bundle D, which is parallel to A.

54
Q

Now how would we illustrate this on a demand curve for good 1 when the price increases for good 1 ( both goods are normal goods)

A

1) We can identify the original bundle A and quantity x1A on the RHS
2) Price goes up and consumer goes to bundle C, we can identify this on demand curve( C is higher price, less Qd) Now connect the uncompensated demand dots. Utility is changing on this line. near the 2 prices on the y axis we can put letters assigned E and F and we can find CS on demand curve ECAF. ( WE READ FROM TOP RIGHT TO LEFT DOWN)
3) With compensating variation on the indifference curve, it is a parallel shift upwards until it touches the original indifference curve, which is B, with a parallel shift from C to B, its just a horizontal movement in the demand curve diagram and but we only focus on were b is in relation C in terms of quantities, B is on the right ( higher quantity so we show that on demand diagram. Now B is on the same indifference curve as A so we can join that line together to get compensated demand. We can highlight the CV now on the demand curve it is EBAF
4) Also notice the uncompensated line is more elastic than the compensated,( there is a greater reduction in the uncompensated demand for x1 than there is the compensated demand).
5) NOW with EV the reduction in income downwards from original BL to a new budget line which is tangent to the new indifference curve, allocates a new bundle D. D is parallel to A, so this is a horizontal to A on the demand curve. We only need to look at quantities and it is on the left to A. so we show on the demand diagram, it is before B tho in terms of quantities so make that clear on the diagram. As C and D are on the same indifference curve, we can highlight a compensated demand, which obvi is still less elastic than uncompensated demand curve. Now EV is ECDF.
We see that CV>CHANGE IN CV>EV FOR NORMAL GOODS

55
Q

Explain why the uncompensated demand curve is more elastic than the compensated demand curve?

A

The uncompensated demand captures the subsitution and income effect, whereas the compensated demand curve captures the substation effect so the reduction in quantity is smaller here.

56
Q

We know for a price increase if the goods are normal then CV>CHANGE IN CS>EV what if the is a price decrease?

A

The reverse happens

Then EV>Change in Cs>CV

57
Q

What is the diminishing marginal utility of income?

A

The diminishing marginal utility of income suggests that as an individual’s income increases, the extra benefit to that individual decreases ( utility decreases). This is because each subsequent dollar is satisfying less and less urgent wants.

When an individuals income is low, the marginal utility of income of another dollar is high. ( utility increases)

58
Q

What is the initutive reason why CV>EV when both goods are normal and the price increases for good 1?

A

The best way to explain this is the diminishing marginal utility of income. Adding income means consuming more, which lowers utility at the margin. In contrast taking income away means consuming less, which raises utlitiy at the margin. So this means adding income is not the same in utility terms as taking income awy. EV involves taking income away… whereas CV involves adding it back on ( if we are dealing with price increase) It requires more money to raise utility than to reduce it.

59
Q

What is the initution why for normal good EV > CV if prices fall?

A

because the marginal utility of income is higher at the new price
level, so less cash income needs to be taken away in order to get the consumer back to their original utility level.

60
Q

Quickly to summarise the subsitution and income effect for Normal goods are what?

A

They are both negative so reinforce each other

61
Q

What difference between CV AND EV arises from what and what happens if there isn’t this effect?

A

The difference in EV and CV arises from the income effect

CV = CHANGE IN CS = EV

62
Q

Show a rise in price for an inferior good( fall in income you consume more of the good) ( good 1) on a diagram and explain it using subsitution and income effect Good 2 is a normal good? What effect dominates?

A

1)Originally we are at bundle A, increase in price of good 1, means budget line pivots inwards, we don’t allocate bundle C yet.
2) To show SUB AND INCOME effect, we draw a dashed budget line parallel from new budget line up to original indifference curve then we indicate point B. the movement from A to B is the subsitution effect.
3) Now as good 1 is an inferior good, we are going to be on the right of B. also Good B is a normal good so consumption for good 2 falls too, which is less than what we were consuming at A.
4) so point C, will be inbetween A and B but beneath A.
Overall the subsitution effect > income effect if not point ( IC>SC) C would to the right of A( Giffen good )

63
Q

First of all draw CV AND EV on an indifference map and explain it again, assuming prices went up for good 1 for an inferior good.

A

1) Originally at bundle A, prices rise, budget line pivots inwards and we go to bundle C as good 1 is an inferior good remember its in b4 A and below A , as good 2 is a normal good.
2) To compensate the consumer, we will give them income just enough so they are on the same utility as before to get bundle B.
3) For EV, we need to now reduce income from original BL till its tangent to new IC to get bundle D.

64
Q

Now how would we illustrate this on a demand curve for good 1 when the price increases for good 1 and good 1 is an inferior good and good 2 a normal good.

A

1) We can identify bundle A on the right hand side of the diagram
2) Prices for good 1 increase, so budget line pivots inwards and we arrive at another bundle C, which is a uncompensated demand shift ( we explained this in the last flashcard why its there), C constitutes to a lower quantity and higher price, so we show this on the demand curve. We can connect C and A which gives the uncompensated demand. We can also Find Consumer surplus. If we Give E to price P1B and F to P1A. Consumer surplus is ECAF ( captures the compensated and uncompensated demand)
3) For CV, we want to add income to compensate them back to the original utility, so this is a parallel shift from original indifference curve from C upwards and we get bundle B. On the demand diagram B to C is a parallel shift, so its horizontal and B is on the left of C. As B and A are on the same indifference curve we can connect the compensated demand up which is more elastic than uncompensated demand. CV = EBAF
4) For EV, we want to reduce income which is as bad a price change, so have a fake budget line going down until its parallel to the NEW IC. We get to bundle D ( on the right of C). D is a parallel shift from A, so this is horizontal on the demand curve and D is on the right of A. As C and D are on the same iC we can join the 2 dots together to get compensated demand at utilty ub. EV = ECDF.
EV > CHANGE IN CS> CV

65
Q

Why is the COMPENSATED DEMAND CURVES ELASTIC THAN THE UNCOMPENSATED DEMAND CURVE?

A

The uncompensated demand reduction in x1 is much smaller than the reduction in x1 from a negative subsitution effect from compensated demand.

66
Q

We know that for an Inferior good EV> Change in CS>CV. when price of good 1 goes up, what happens when price of good 1 goes down?

A

CV> CHANGE IN CS > EV

67
Q

Draw a diagram when good 1 is a giffen good and good 2 is a normal good and the price of good 1 increases? ( remember income effect > substitution effect. ( EXPLAIN THIS )

A

The key thing is that the substitution effect on demand for good 1 (consume less of good 1 because it is relatively more expensive) is outweighed by the income effect in the opposite direction (consume more of good 1 because you feel poorer). This means that the total effect involves an increase in consumption of good 1 and the uncompensated demand curve for good 1 slopes upwards ( for an inferior good it doesn’t outweigh, so still slopes downwards)

68
Q

First of all draw CV AND EV on an indifference map and explain it again, assuming prices went up for good 1 for a giffen good?

A

1) Originally at bundle A, prices rise, budget line pivots inwards and we go to bundle C as good 1 is a giffen good, c is on the on the right of A below A.
2) We need to compensate the consumer for this price rise, so therefore, we add income up to where the fake budget line tangent to the original indifference curve to get bundle b.
3) With EV, we need to reduce income, which is equivalent to the price change, so we reduce income, until it is tangent to the new indifference curve and we get point D, which is further to the righf than C.

69
Q

Now how would we illustrate this on a demand curve for good 1 when the price increases for good 1 and good 1 is a giffen good and good 2 a normal good. find out what bigger EV CV and what would it be if the price fell.

A

ADD TO THE DIAGRAM E AND F

1) Original bundle A and quantity, we can identify this on the RHS. As prices rise for good 1, the budget line pivots inwards and we arrive at another bundle C( parallel to B), we can show this on demand curve, C ( REMEMBER GIFFEN GOOD, so there is an increase in quantity hence price must be higher) We can join And C together to get uncompensated demand that slopes upwards. The CS is ECAF.
2) Now we want to compensate consumers, so we add income from new budget to the original indifference curve, to get bundle B. B is parallel to C and is on the left of C, so on the demand curve it is horizontal but to the left of . As B and A are on the same IC we can join them up to get compensated demand at UA. The CV = EBAF.
3) For EV we want to take away income which is( so parallel shift from original budget line (A) ) down to when its tangent to new IC) so get to bundle D. D is parallel to A, so its horizontal on the demand curve but its on the right of A, and the quantity is higher than C. As D and C are on the same IC we can join the dots to get compensated demand for that UB. EV = ECDF.

So EV> CHANGE IN CS> CV it would be the other way round if prices decreased.

70
Q

When we have quasi linear preferences and income is enough ( so we have interior solution Show EV, CV and CS on a diagram ( explain in your head)

A

CV = EV = CHANGE IN CONSUMER SURPLUS, AS THERE IS NO INCOME EFFECT. ( WHEN THE INCOME ELASTICITY OF THE UNCOMPENSATED DEMAND =0, THE INCOME EFFECT OF PRICE CHANGE = 0.
REMEMEBER THERE IS AN INCOME EFFECT ( IF WE ARE AT THE CORNER SOLUTION)

71
Q

Explain intuitively why CV = EV when there is no income effect.

A
72
Q

What do we use when income effects are small and large

A
73
Q

Example fuel tax

1) Fuel is a large share of expenditure so the income effect is significant
2) The government may need to compensate people for the increase in tax
3) May want to know how different groups are affected
(e. g. pensioners, commuters etc)
1) What does it mean for our 3 monitory measures
2) What is relevant here
3) What is relevant here

A

1) Consumer surplus isn’t a great approximation
2) CV relevant
3) EV relevant

74
Q

We are now going to look whether when we tax a good whether the revenue generated from that enough to compensate for the welfare lose caused by tax.
What do we use to assess the effects of a tax on groups?

A

We are going to use EV.

75
Q

Show the effect of an excise tax on good 1 that raises price from P1A to PLA + t where t is the tax, assuming both goods are normal goods. Then compute EV.
What is the budget constraint btw for bundle b and gradient of the new budget line?

A

EV ( how much income reduction would be equivalent to this tax decrease, you take the original budget line and shift it down until it touches the indifference curve of lower utility is, and we get bundle C.
(p1A + T)x1b + p2x2B = m

76
Q

Now how do we show the revenue raised from tax?

A

We draw a line going bundle B with same gradient as original budget line through the new bundle.
The higher intercept going through bundle A tells us the income needed to purchase bundle A.
The line going through bundle b tells us the income i would have needed at the original prices to purchase the new bundle ( as you can see less money is needed) the money went to the government. so revenue is r/p2 ( remember we want q)

77
Q

How can we show the tax revenue in terms of the budget constraint?

A

Rearrange the budget new budget line m-p1aX1b - p2bx2b ( m - expenditure of new bundle at old prices)

78
Q

What can we say about the revenue raised by the government in comparison to EV( what is EV)?

A

The revenue gained is less than EV ( the revenue raised isn’t enough to cover the loss of the consumer( EV is a financial measure telling us the cost of the consumer in monetary terms
The gap between EV- R/p2 = excess burden of tax EB/p2

79
Q

Why is it a problem that the revenue raised isn’t big enough to cover CV assuming the 2 goods are normal goods( if not the answer might change) ?

A

Because CV>EV, and CV is what we need to compensate the consumer for whats happened, if the revenue raised by the government is not big enough to cover EV, its defientely not enough to cover CV. ( so we can not subsidise consumer and put them back where they were.

80
Q

If the 2 goods are PC, then would the tax raised be enough to cover CV?

A

Example 2: perfect complements (no sub effect, but there is an income effect)

R = EV < CV
Tax still not enough to cover CV

81
Q

How do we know that if there is an excise tax on good 1 consumers will always consume less of good 1 and there will always be an excise burden of tax?

A

There is a subsistution effect, if there is a subsitution effect, there will always be excise burden ( PS, CB, QUASI LINEAR)

82
Q

What is the best way for the government to raise revenue? AND WHAT ARE DRAW BACKS OF IT

A

Lump sum tax ( not on the product, just takeaway income, meaning no subsitution effect.)
With lump sum taxes the loss to the consumer measured by the
equivalent variation is equal to the tax revenue, i.e. there is no
deadweight loss to taxation.
With taxes that are not lump sum there is a deadweight loss unless
the two goods are perfect complements.
But for the tax to be lump sum it would have to unaffected by any
decisions the consumer makes, which in practice means that it would
be the same for each consumer. This is politically infeasible in many
countries, and in the judgement of most people ethically unacceptable.

83
Q

What is a lump sum tax, if the government replaces the excise tax by a lump sum tax which raises the same revenue as the exicse tax is the consumer better or worse off?

A

A tax is lump sum if nothing the consumer does can change the amount paid. The effect of a lump sum tax is to shift the orgiinal budget line down to the parallel dashed budget line. Point B is chosen with excise tax is still feasible so the consumers cannot be worse off, the consumer is better off and will be at bundle D if substitution is possible.

84
Q

Suppose the weights are based on consumers consumption. Suppose also that the inflation rate as measured by this price index is 3% but the consumer’s income increases by 2%. Is it possible that the the consumer is better off?

A

It is possible the consumer can be better off in the case of Perfect subisututes, prices increases of average CPI doesn’t have to be for both goods, it can also be for only be for one good, meaning that. E.g. lets say we have a U(x1,x2) = 3x1 + 2x2. Consumer is consuming all of good 1. ( relative price = 1/1. Now suppose price of good 1 increases by 3 this means that consumers will switch to good 2. if income increases by 2 percentage , there will be a shift and consumers will be better off.