Vertical Restraints Flashcards
Two ways to evade § 2 liability for vertical intrabrand price restraints
- The agreement was reasonable (it was not an “unreasonable restraint on trade”)
- There was never an agreement.
Fundamental Fact to Understand RPM Economics
Manufacturer sells to retailer at wholesale price. The difference between the wholesale price and the retail price = the retail margin (or retail markup).
The retail markup is the manufacturer’s “cost” of the retail service.
When a manufacturer imposes min RPM it INCREASES the retail margin/markup (since competition can’t keep forcing retailers to keep lowering price). The increase in retail margin/markup GOES TO THE RETAILER.
Which is “bad” for the manufacturer (it wants the markup/margin to be as small as possible consistent with efficient distribution of their product). So there MUST be procompetitive reasons they are doing this…
Anticompetitive red herrings for min RPM
- Reduces intrabrand competition
This is true… but anytime a manufacturer sets any kind of standard about how its product is to be sold it reduces competition between retailers.
Sometimes, restraints on intrabrand competition are necessary to promote interbrand competition. So this is not an anticompetitive harm. - Min. RPM raises prices
True… but there mere fact that something a manufacturer does raises prices does not mean that practice is anticompetitive (ex: advertising raises prices and is incredibly competitive).
Actual anticompetitive harms of min RPM
- Facilitates retailer collusion
Two big hurdles to collusion are establishing an agreement and policing an agreement.
Min. RPM makes both of these a lot easier. Easier to spot cheating. Easier to make an agreement. - Facilitates Manufacturer level collusion
- reduces incentive for manuf to cheat (min RPM insures cheater won’t increase sales)
- makes cheating more visible - Exclusionary Device for Dominant Manufacturer
- Retailers love RPM (guaranteed profit margin & know rivals can’t undersell you)
- If the dominant manufacture has RPM, they may exclude other manufacturers from shelves. - Exclusionary Device for Dominant Retailer
- If there is a dominant retailer that manufacturers HAD to be in business with, the dominant retailer could demand RPM (to prevent being undersold by online/other retailers) or they won’t buy/give desirable shelf space.
Procompetitive benefits of min RPM
- Avoids free riding on point of sale services
- Manufacturer wants retailer to have POS services to make their product more attractive to consumers.
- People will go get the POS services, then buy online/bix box–running POS service dealer out of business. - Facilitates entry of new brands
- The first retailers to give up shelf space for a new brand, “pioneer retailers,” incur costs by promoting this new product. Once brand is established and other retailers want in, without RPM, other retailers could undersell the pioneer retailer. - Encourages sales-enhancing retailer services that are not subject to free riding (favorable shelf space, attractive product displays, etc.)
- RPM markup incentivizes retailers to give products better shelf space because they get a better/guaranteed cut from the retail margin.
- Can set min RPM with liberal termination clause if the retailer doesn’t sell enough units.
This incentivizes retailer to come up with the best ways to sell the product, rather than having manuf. trying to contract for them.
Min RPM ROR overview
(1) Plaintiff must prove the pre-requisites to one of the 4 theories of RPM anticompetitive harm. (if not, D wins). Plaintiff’s prima facie case
(2) Defendant must prove that the RPM achieves one of the 3 procompetitive benefits. (if not, P wins)
(3) Plaintiff may then show that the procompetitive benefit could be achieved equally effectively using substantially less restrictive means. (if P makes that showing, P wins)
(4) If P doesn’t show substantially less restrictive alternative ^^ then court balances the likely competitive effects.
Min RPM ROR AT Harm Prerequisites: Facilitates Dealer/Retailer Collusion
(1) Dealers/Retailers stand to benefit from it. This requires:
(A) Retailer’s market is susceptible to collusion (some can’t be – too many dealers, susceptible to cheating, etc) AND
(B) Either:
- Manufacturer has market power (Brand without close substitutes) OR
- Basically all manufacturers use RPM (so customers can’t switch away)
(2) Manufacture has to concede to it (which they won’t want to since they want retail margins as low as possible). So when would they concede? Only if:
- (A) Dealers have market power AND
(Manufactuer REALLY wants dealer to carry their brand so has no choice but to give into the higher margins)
- (B) Forward integration is impracticable
(Manufacturer can’t just open a retail outlet themselves and bypass the retailers)
Min RPM ROR AT Harms Prerequisites: Facilitates Manufacturer Collusion
(1) Manufacturer market is susceptible to collusion
- Concentrated,
- Fungible, or
- Barriers to entry
(2) Retail Price Maintenance is widely used among manufacturers
- If only one is using, it is not likely being used to sure up manufacturer-level collusion.
Min RPM ROR AT Harm Prerequisite: Exclusionary Device for Dominant Manufacturer
(1) RPM must be a significant benefit to dealers (provide a nice profit margin)
(2) Dealers subject to the RPM comprise a cobstantial portion of available market outlets for competing manufacturers products
- If rivals loose access to favorable shelf in a grocery store, but have a ton of other places they sell a lot of product still, not as big of a deal.
Min RPM ROR AT Harm Prerequisite: Exclusionary Device for Dominant Retailer
(1) Initiated by a dealer with market power
- If the manufacturer initiated, it’s not likely being used for this purpose.
(2) Brands upon which dealer procured RPM comprise a significant portion of sales in the dealer/retailer market.
Min RPM ROR: How can D evade liability if they cannot prove RPM achieves a procompetitive benefit?
The Colgate exception for purely unilateral action
The manufacturer simply announces its intention not to do business with dealers that sell below a certain price level and then does no more than abide by that announced policy.
Park Davis: If the manufacturer does anything more than announce its policy up front and then follow it—for example, if it “reminds” dealers of its policy or encourages them to abide by the resale restriction—the Colgateexception will not apply. (The court will infer that any dealer who follows the pricing policy after having been “reminded” or “encouraged” has agreed with the manufacturer. Thus the weird procedures used by Ping.)
How do we treat Maximum Resale Price Maintance (RPM)
Since state oil = not a single successful max RPM case. We can pretty confidently say max RPM is per se legal. Only ever saw in Globe democrat scenerio: worried about distributors exercising market power so they limit their price
Since that’s the only place we ever see it, we can say its per se legal
How do we treat Consumer restriction agreements
Still theoretically able to establish liability, but the only real viable theory is dealer/retailer collusion (don’t want to compete for market, so let’s have manufacturers split up market for us).
Plaintiff has to demonstrate that this is what was going on when the manufacturer set up exclusive sales territories.
But most of the time the manufacturer set up these exclusive sales territories to avoid freeriding, so there aren’t a lot of successful challenges to these practices.
Avoiding Vertical Intrabrand “Agreements”
- Confinement (Agency)
- Manufacturer who wants to control can retail title even after it passes into the hands of the retailer.
- Technically no RPM because no sale.
- AND two parties that are part of the same economic enterprise cannot conspire – Copperweld
But kind of dead/less applicable now since Dr. Miles (per se RPM) is dead (RPM is ROR). - Colgate Exception **
There was never an agreement, it was just a unilateral announcement of our policy (policy is = we don’t sell products to retailers who sell under $X). So no agreement between anyone. This is just what we do.
CANNOT do anything beyond announcing the policy and enforcing the policy. Warnings, reminders, encouragement, discussing boundaries, etc. will be held to be evidence an agreement, and courts will infer one. – Park Davis
- Ping Brief points out how hard it is to comply with Colgate. Colgate policies are difficult to implement because if basically do anything, taken to agree with dealer and hence liable.
Exclusive Dealing Anticompetitive harms
- Anticompetitive foreclosure of available marketing outlets (*biggest one)
- If the exclusive dealing arrangements foreclose so many sales opportunities (marketing outlets) that your rivals costs (RRC raise rivals cost) are raised either because
- (A) Dominant firm has taken up so many of the available marketing opportunities it drives rivals to cut back on production and thus fall below minimum efficient scale
- (B) Dominant firm forecloses opportunities that forces rivals to be relegated to costlier marketing/sales outlets, driving up their cost. - Reduced price competition
- Incidents of price competition are reduced.