The Eurozone Flashcards
The Eurozone
The Eurozone is a common currency area or a monetary union.
» Eurozone also referred to as the European Monetary Union (EMU).
The Eurozone is a variant of a fixed exchange rate regime. Therefore, when looking at the Eurozone:
» monetary policy in an open economy under fixed exchange rates.
The theory of the optimum currency area
The theory of an optimum currency area (Mundell, 1961):
» points to the costs and benefits of a country giving up independent
monetary policy and an independent exchange rate. Considerations of joining a common currency area.
For example, why did the following countries join the Eurozone?
» Germany:
‘Level playing field’ where other European countries could not gain a competitive advantage.
» Italy, Spain and Greece: Low and stable inflation.
Microeconomic benefits of joining a common currency area
higher trade and investment due to elimination of foreign exchange rate risk
resource savings
increased competition
increased liquidity in financial markets
- it is argued that monetary integration stimulates higher trade and investment, due to the fact that adoption of a single currency eliminates foreign exchange rate risk.
- Real resource savings arise from eliminating transactions costs that are incurred by cur- rency conversion.
- Competition in goods and labour markets would be expected to increase due to greater ease of price and wage comparisons. More competition, in turn, would be expected to produce both static and dynamic efficiency gains
- Monetary union is expected to increase the liquidity of financial markets. This is of par- ticular benefit for small member countries. More liquid financial markets can also bring dangers of resource misallocation
Macroeconomic benefits of joining a common currency area
reduction in exchange rate volatility
delegation authority for monetary policy: importation of stable inflation
avoidance of competitive devaluation by members of a CCA
costs joining a common currency area
giving up an independent monetary policy and exchange rate regime
The Eurozone’s performance in its first 10 years
Eurozone’s performance as a whole prior to the GFC was good. Monetary policy:
» ECB’s performance was broadly successful. Fiscal policy: less successful.
Member countries individual performance pre-GFC was heterogeneous.
Indicators of imbalances
The real exchange rate.
Current account balances.
Public sector debt.
Private sector debt.
Variation in inflation in member countries.
The Eurozone policy regime
Maastricht Treaty 1992.
» Monetary policy - ECB responsible for:
responding to Euro-area wide (common) shocks.
delivering low and stable inflation in the Eurozone (Euro area).
» Fiscal policy - National governments responsible for:
fiscal sustainability and stabilising country-specific & asymmetric
shocks.
the Stability & Growth Pact (SGP) - specifies limit on national budget deficits (< 3%) and on government debt–to–GDP ratio (< 60%). SGP aims to prevent policies that threaten the ECB’s inflation objectives.
» Supply-side policy
National labour & product markets and supply-side policies determine equilibrium unemployment.
The Eurozone policy regime
Maastricht Treaty 1992.
» Monetary policy - ECB responsible for:
responding to Euro-area wide (common) shocks.
delivering low and stable inflation in the Eurozone (Euro area).
» Fiscal policy - National governments responsible for:
fiscal sustainability and stabilising country-specific & asymmetric
shocks.
the Stability & Growth Pact (SGP) - specifies limit on national budget deficits (< 3%) and on government debt–to–GDP ratio (< 60%). SGP aims to prevent policies that threaten the ECB’s inflation objectives.
» Supply-side policy
National labour & product markets and supply-side policies determine equilibrium unemployment.
Interest rate differentials
UIP condition with default risk
he risk-adjusted UIP condition says that a CCA member’s interest rate will be above the CCA interest rate to the extent that its nominal exchange rate is expected to depreciate and its risk of default on government debt exceeds that of the benchmark CCA government.
ln the Eurozone, the benchmark government debt is that issued by Germany (so-called German Bunds) and exchange rate risk is zero (as exchange rates are fixed between members). Hence, the difference between German and, for example, Greek interest rates on ten-year bonds reflects only the difference in default risk.
During the Eurozone’s first decade, interest differentials with Germany on long-term gov- ernment bonds were very small. How can this be explained?
- The markets viewed the likelihood of a default by a Eurozone government as being very low. For example, they considered the risk of a systemic banking crisis in a Eurozone member that would require a government rescue of banks as a very low probability event.
- The markets did not connect the divergent performance among Eurozone members with the possible implications for government solvency.
- The markets did not believe the Eurozone’s ‘no bail-out clause’ and took the view that any problem in one member government’s ability to service its debts would be solved by the ECB and/or by the other Eurozone governments.
In terms of the relationships among member governments and between them and the ECB, the central elements were:
- Government to government: the ‘no bail-out’ clause stated that other member govern- ments could not be called upon to bail out a government in trouble.
- ECB to government: the ‘no monetary financing’ clause stated that the ECB would not provide credit to governments {i.e. it would not be the lender of last resort to govern- ments).
- The fiscal rules: the entry rules for deficits and debt and the Stability and Growth Pact, which were designed to support {1) and (2).
Stabilisation in the Eurozone: common shocks
Two levels of stabilisation
1. At the Eurozone level (supra-national).
2. At the country-specific level (national).
ECB works as a single monetary policy maker in the Eurozone. ECB responds to common shocks: shocks that affects all members.
» By choosing the real interest rate to achieve its inflation target.
Stabilisation in the Eurozone: country-specific shocks - options available