PPF, indifference curve, interdependencies between conflict and economics, pareto efficiency, rational choice model (and critiques), taxonomy of goods, utility functions Flashcards
Explain the 6 Interdependencies of conflict economics
- choice
- economic conditions affect conflict
- conflict affects the economy (5 D’s)
- conflict as a mode of wealth appropriation
- conflict as business organizing
- security of people as a fundamental service
Conflict is a choice:
1. Economics is largely the study of choices people make in a scarce world - conflict is a choice that stems from rational and irrational behaviour
- Economic conditions affect conflict
a. Poverty, unemployment, low growth, economic inequality. Low education, resource dependence, low trade/FDI openness, and territoriality all lead to higher risks of conflict - Conflict affects the economy
a. 5 D’s
b. Diversion of resources into the military, or weapons instead of more productive means - looking at things like military expenditure
c. Destruction of people and property - rebuilding a population and infrastructure that comes at a loss due to war
d. disruption of economic activities through diminishments in capital, trade, growth, and household work
e. Displacement - internally and internationally due to fleeing persecution
f. Development difficulties in a postwar context how challenging it is to recover the country’s institutions and economy - especially because many people will have different interests and the solution will mostly likely be imposed by the most powerful - Conflict is a mode of wealth appropriation
a. Lootable assets, that is assets that can be appropriated by different actors through force - Conflict as business organizing
a. When a group decides to engage in conflict, it must operate analogous to a company, it must make decisions on resource allocation in order to achieve its goals. When a rebel organization decides to mobilize, they need funds to gain support and buy arms - Security of people is a fundamental service
a. Economics looks at people acquiring services like food and clothing, but security is absolutely fundamental and demanded by people.
Explain the assumptions of rationality and what this means for an equilibrium
Actors are assumed to be rational meaning they have a set of options and alternatives and choose the best one that achieves their consistent preferences
o The assumption that there are well defined preferences
o Not much on the origin or content of those preferences - the formation of these preferences are out of the subject for the most part
o Instead, we take the preferences of actors as given
Equilibrium is coordination among the actors so no actor has an incentive to change its position, for example, the equilibrium of supply and demand
What do points inside/outside/on the line of the PPF represent and what inputs determine the PPF (look at photo on notes page 3
Points inside the PPF (such as A) represent combinations of civilian and military goods production levels that are possible, but are inefficient; it must mean that we are not using resources wisely, or perhaps not at all. This is called productive inefficiency, compared to allocative efficiency (or Pareto) which occurs when it’s not possible to improve one individual’s well-being without hurting the others.
Points on the line (such as B) are possible and 4 efficient; the economy is operating at capacity, efficiently, and we cannot get more civilian goods without reducing military goods production, or vice versa.
Points like C are better than B, but are not attainable for this economy given its amount of productive resources and level of technology.
Also assume that the production depends on capital (K) and labour (L)- so C = f(Lc, Kc)
M = g(Mc, Kc)
Explain why the slope is negative on the PPF - and how it resembles the opportunity cost (which is also the marginal rate of transformation)
The slope of the PPF is negative to illustrate that when adding more of one good you lose some of the other
o This is called opportunity cost, basically how much of one good your giving up when adding another good
o Calculated by calculating the increase of the new input (m1 to m2), by looking at the units given up to attain that good (c1 to c2)
The slope, opportunity cost, and marginal rate of transformation are basically the same thing on the PPF
What is the marginal rate of substitution on the indifference curve
Marginal rate of substitution is on the indifference curve – representing how much of one good I need to forgo the consumption of another good to leave me indifferent. The marginal rate of transformation is the technology that allows me change production of one good to another good and is shown on the PPF. The MRS must equal the MRT on the graph.
What is the indifference curve, why does it slope down, is higher more preferred, what is diminishing marginal utility, and why can’t they cross one another
The indifference curve shows the overall well-being and utility, and the higher along the curve the better the well-being and utility. The indifference or U curve also has the following characteristics:
U curves always slope downwards which means that if I give up some of one good, I need to get more of the other to leave me “indifferent”.
Higher indifference curves are more preferred because the commodities are goods and preferences and transitive, for example, it would be more preferred to have basket a (x=3 and y=4) than basket b (x=4 and y=2). This is on the assumption in economics that more is always better.
These curves tend to have steep slopes at the left (top) and flatter slopes at the right (bottom) illustrating the idea of diminishing utility in consumption. If I am consuming a lot of civilian goods (left, top) then typically I am happy to give up a lot of these for a little bit of military goods (a point up and to the left on a curve), but if I am consuming very little civilian goods and lots of military goods (lower right), to reduce civilian goods further I would need to be given a lot of military goods to compensate for a small decline in civilian goods consumption. The principle of diminishing marginal utility is clearer if you think of combinations of goods like beer and pizza, coffee and donuts, etc.
§ Example, on point a on the curve to b you give up 2 units of Y to get 1 unit of X. If you move from point a to c you would give up 3 units of Y to get 3 units of X
§ The marginal rate of substation, between X and Y at any given point is the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve at the same point - we can think of the MRS as how much the consumer is willing to give up of Y per added unit of X. So we know the subjective value of X in terms of Y, at a point where there 4 Y and 1 X, we can say that the value of a unit of X is equivalent to 4 Y.
§ Again though the MRS has a diminishing subjective value, with more and more consumption of X, we may begin to value Y higher
o These curves cannot cross one another, because it would violate the principle that more is preferred to less – the point is that the indifference curve is a consumption bundle at the points along the curve represent the other consumption combinations that would leave me “indifferent”
Utility or indifference curves further from the origin are preferred to those closer to the origin (marked 0).
Explain trade specialization, how it affects the PPF, and indifference curve, and how it relates to opportunity cost and comparative advantage (refer to picture on page 5)
The tradeoff in the previous PPF is internal, meaning this an autarky where there’s no trade, but let’s assume that the opportunity cost of producing military goods was lower in the country than on the world market
Producing one unit of m costs one unit of c in the country
Producing one unit of m costs two unit of c in the world
Therefore it would specialize in m
For that, the country would specialize in the good they have a lower opportunity cost in, export m, and then import the remaining c that they gave up by producing m
With international trade, the country can improve its welfare. Let’s say that relative to the rest of the world, this country is relatively worse at producing civilian goods. To get a few extra units of civilian goods it needs to give up quite a few military goods, so the domestic price line PD is 6 quite flat. For the rest of the world, the price line is steeper (PW) because at the margin the resources removed from military production would produce more units of food than is the case domestically for the country. In this case, the country could move production from B to P, and then trade along the Pw line to consume at point T, taking advantage of international pries and trading opportunities to export Mexp amount of guns and import Cimp amount of butter. This process allows the country to consume on indifference curve UH, which is clearly preferred to indifference curve UB. This is one diagrammatic exposition of the benefits of international trade. However, you can also see that removing trading opportunities through war would reduce welfare. This effect is referred to in the text as the “disruption effect”
Therefore, trade allows the country to obtain a higher indifference curve, or a higher level of well-being and utility - this specialization is called the comparative advantage
Economic costs of conflict: the diversion of resources, explain how it affects the PPF and indifference curve (graph on page 7)
The diversion of resources into the military because of a conflict causes a movement along the curve which reflects that more military goods are being produced at the expense of civilian goods. Increasing military production, and decreasing civilian goods production, if done efficiently (i.e. remaining on the PPF) leads to a production choice of something like W, and by definition being on utility curve U2 means lower welfare than the previous U1 at point B. Socially, however, for W to be the preferred point of production, war must cause a change in the country’s social preferences to favour guns, so the utility curves would have to shift to something like Uw. Technically W is still efficient in the sense that there is no feasible Pareto improvement that is possible, i.e. the economy is on the PPF, and more of one good necessarily means less of the other.
In addition, technically I cannot compare U1 and Uw, as these are different preference patterns. However, logically, if war has shaped social preferences to look like Uw by imposing some kind of psychological constraint or military imperative, then logically U1 is better than Uw because the latter is. In some sense, forces by the imperative of war, while the former reflects social choices unconstrained by war, though it is an interesting point of debate. You can also think that in moving from B to W the economy may suffer some period of inefficiency, operating within the PPF as production processes switch over and new skills have to be learned. One way of potentially illustrating this effect is to consider the transition path from B to W marked with the purple line.
Economic costs of war: the destruction of people and property (graph on page 7)
The destruction of people and property, along with the displacement of people with fewer workers in the economy, the PPF shrinks inwards showing now a decreased capacity to produce goods. In the case of resource destruction, the economy’s PPF contracts from PPFB to PPFw, the economy moves from B to W and clearly the society is worse off in terms of welfare when compared to the pre-war situation.
Economic costs of conflict: Disruption of trade
Disruption of trade - with conflict more countries will not trade with the conflicted country, so the PPF will start to look as if the country is in an autarky, which will decrease the indifference curve and lower overall production
Military spending and economic growth: explain crowding out, crowding in, and the growth spinoff effect (also consider counterpoints for each argument)
Crowding out: let’s assume that higher investment in the civilian sector would lead to better machines and factories so improving capital and causing larger stock prices next year leading to a higher PPF - in this case, producing more military goods will be associated with crowding out or a decrease of growth because that money that could’ve been spent on investment is being used elsewhere
Crowding in: let’s assume that the country is experiencing a recession and has underutilized production, then an increase in military production could increase the wages of those workers and lead them to spend more in the civilian sector, so thus increased military spending could lead to higher production in both the military and civilian sector
o Counterpoint: we see echoes of this argument today in terms of announcements that cuts in defence spending will be bad for the economy. That does not mean that war is good, though, even if military spending can stimulate an economy.
o While it is true that defence spending can have an expansionary fiscal effect and thus assist in economic recovery from a low point on the business cycle, so would spending on schools or hospitals. It is important, therefore, to keep in mind the ultimate utility of the expenditures: are we better off having more bombers and tanks or more teachers and operating rooms?
o The Vietnam War was a good reminder to many people in the West that war is not good for the economy (Melman, 1972). The macroeconomic effects on the US economy were huge (higher inflation, larger trade deficits, exchange rate problems, increased government budget deficits and public debt) and the microeconomic costs were also substantial (distorted labour markets, concentrated market structures, procurement problems, regulatory failure) let alone the human costs of battle deaths. And this is to say nothing of the war’s effects on Vietnam, which were simply devastating.
Growth spinoff: greater military spending can possibly lead to growth spinoffs in such as increases in education (providing education to soldiers) or advances in technology, then these positive benefits cross over to other sectors and cause the PPF to shift outwards having a more spread out curve reaching production levels that would have not been possible with the previous capital and labour inputs
Counterpoint: This is also true, but it avoids the question of whether such research and development would have been more beneficial had it been directed to civilian needs first. Of course, the diversion of useful resources into military research and arming is only one cost. Much higher are the costs of actual war, which entails death and destruction of often appalling proportions. There is the enormous damage and suffering from military and civilian deaths, the destruction of buildings, infrastructure, goods, assets, the environment, and social structures. These costs are enormous and are profoundly difficult to measure or even comprehend.
Use the graph on page 10. to explain changes in the PPF due to crowding out, crowding in, and growth spin-offs
The PPF can also be used to illustrate possible effects on growth, including crowding out of productive investment, crowding in of aggregate expenditure (as in a recession, when operating within the PPF) and potential spin-off effects of investment in military technology. In the diagram below, these possible competing forces can be represented by smaller outward shifts of the PPF (to PPF2) or larger shifts outward (PPF3). The black arrows illustrate what might happen when military expenditures have a positive effect on future economic growth, for example through increased research and development (R&D). More military spending (lower right black arrow) leads to a greater expansion in the PPF (to PPF3) than when there is less military spending (upper left black arrow, to PPF2).
When military expenditures crowd out productive investment or more productive R&D, future production options decline and the blue arrows illustrate the relative effects of different production combinations. Finally, there could be a positive effect of military spending on aggregate expenditure, moving the economy from an inefficient point D inside the PPF to a point closer to or on the PPF; this was the argument about rearmament in the interwar period. As noted earlier, though, it is unclear why military spending would be superior to civilian goods expenditure in increasing aggregate demand.
Explain the demand and supply curve, and why they shift
The D curve shows at any given price the corresponding quantity demanded, holding preferences, incomes, and other prices fixed
o Negative slope due to the law of demand, in which price and quantity are inveresely related - higher price, lower quantity and vice-versa
The S curve shows at any given price the corresponding quantity supplied, holding technology and input prices fixed
Positive slope due to law of supply, which price and quantity are directly related - higher price, higher quantity
If one of the things we hold constant changes the entire curve shifts
If cereal is a normal good than a rise in income will cause a rise in demand causing a shift to the right, showing that any given price consumers are willing to buy more quantity
An increase in the price of a substitute good will cause the demand curve to shift to the right, as demand will increase - demand to the left if a decrease in substitute price
Increase in a complement good will decrease demand and shift to the left
Technological improvement will shift supply curve to the right
If input prices increases then costs will be higher and supply will decrease, making it shift to the left
taxonomy of goods, rival versus nonrival, excludable versus nonexcludable
Goods are classified as rival or non-rival:
o Rival good is if one person’s consumption of a unit precludes another person’s consumption of the same unit
Goods are classified as excludable or nonexcludable
Goods are excludable if you can exclude others from its consumption
Rival and excludable: private goods, such as cereal and medicine
Rival and nonexcludable: common-resource good, such as fish in open water
Nonrival and excluduable: club good, such as properiteray website, satellite radio
Nonrival nonexcludable: public good, anti-missile defence system
A goods type is determined by its characteristics and not by the sector that employs it private versus public
Free ride: because public goods are nonrival and nonexcludable each consumer has the inventive to free ride, that is, to share in the consumption of the public good but not in the cost
Free riding leaves producers in the private sector with no incentive to provide the good
Consider common resrouce goods such as water flowing across borders, they are rival because ones consumption prevents the other, but nonexcludable because it flows to different areas, this potentially leads to violent disputes over the dvision of the water, due in large part because of the nonexcludability of the good
Explain pareto efficiency, pareto dominates and dominated (also answer table on page 13)
A Pareto efficient equilibrium is defined as a distribution of resources in which no person can be made better off without making someone else worse off (weak Pareto efficiency makes one person better off but no one worse off; strong Pareto efficiency; all agents are strictly better off). It is not a particularly strict condition, and it includes many resource distribution configurations that may be considered undesirable for other reasons.
· For example, if there are two people and 10 dollars to be divided between them, then any division of that ten dollars that sums up to ten would be Pareto efficient. For example, 5 dollars for both people would be Pareto efficient, but so too would 10 dollars for one person and none for the other.
· A distribution “A” Pareto dominates (is Pareto superior to) distribution “B” if it makes at least one person better off than under B, while making nobody worse off.
The reason why 3, 5, and 7 are pareto efficient is because one or more of the actors in that scenario would reject leaving because it would make them worse off
Some questions to consider is total output of different scenarios and whether a transfer is enforceable, and what the default scenario is
When a scenario is pareto dominated then it is pareto inefficient, a scenario is pareto efficient when it’s not pareto dominated