Part 7: Accounting Information and Asset Pricing Flashcards

1
Q

Fama: sufficient but not necessary conditions of information efficiency

A
  • no transaction costs
  • information is available to all investors free of charge
  • investors have homogeneous priors, they process information equally
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

Definition of informational efficiency from Fama

A

„A market in which prices always ‘fully reflect’

available information is called ‘efficient’.“

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

What does ‘fully reflect’ mean?

A

„Market efficiency requires that in setting the prices of
securities at any time t-1, the market correctly uses
all available information.“

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Levels of informational efficiency

A

• weak
contains all market prices observable up to t-1.
F.e. Past market prices, what is observable

• semi-strong
contains all publicly available information up to t-1,
– which includes market prices.
– Problem: what is „publicly available“?
Not costly accounting information, income statement

• strong
contains all information up to t-1. Private information, like future strategy
– Problem: who knows all? We can never know everything

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

A weaker assumption is the possibility of unlimited arbitrage:

A

– As long as the marginal investor
– has the information available and
– faces no transaction costs,
– he is able to engage in arbitrage activities
– until his arbitrage trading strategy is not yielding any excess return.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

Does accounting matter in informationally efficient markets?

A

• If markets are informationally efficient in a strong sense, (backward-looking)
accounting information might not be of any use.
• However, in reality, we usually assume that markets are informationally efficient
only in a semi-strong sense. In this world, accounting information should provide
new information content and does seem to do so – at least to some extent

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

Accounting in semi-strong informationally efficient markets

A
  • Naive investors are price protected.
  • Recognition versus disclosure does not matter.

• Accounting is one information source from a set of sources
– Other sources can be timelier and thus lead earnings.
– Accounting itself might have little valuation impact (it can still serve as a
verification device and disciplining instrument).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Rational expectations models ‘ impossibly of informationally efficient markets’

A

• Central assumptions:
– Investors possess homogeneous, but incomplete information.
– Additional information is available at cost.
– Investors behave rationally and, thus, can infer information from prices.

• Questions:
– Do investors choose to get informed?
– What is the equilibrium price?

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

What are the incentives to get informed?

A

In real life, markets will never be fully informationally efficient.

– The more efficient they become, the less incentives market participants have to acquire information.
– There is constant arrival of new information and
– constant change in information production cost.
– In addition, information production cost functions are heterogeneous.
• Thus, there will always be information asymmetry on (capital) markets.
• And there will always be an incentive to produce information and to impound it into prices:

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

Is information priced?

A

• Information on capital markets will never be complete.
• Financial accounting has the goal
– to increase the level of information (increase precision of information) and
– to level the playing field (lower information asymmetry).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Information precision in the CAPM-world

A

• In the CAPM-world, investors are homogeneous and as such there is no
information asymmetry between market participants but between
– nature who picks the attributes of the traded assets and
– market participants who have blurred knowledge about these attributes.
• This leads to the inability of market participants to estimate the expected return of
traded assets with optimal precision.
• We refer to this as sub-optimal information precision and assume that the lack of
precision is not causing a bias (i.e., it only influences the variance of expected
returns and not their mean).
• This is also labeled as estimation risk by the literature.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

Information precision vs. information asymmetry

A

• An increase in information precision
(reduction of estimation risk) is priced if it has an impact on undiversifiable risk
components.
• In a large economy this is true if the precision increase has an impact on the
covariance of expected returns.
• If all investors are homogeneously informed,
– investors cannot learn from price and thus
– expected returns can be modeled without focusing on the price mechanism.
• If information precision is heterogeneously distributed across investors,
– information asymmetry arises and, in equilibrium,
– expected returns depend on price (rational expectations).
• Models of information asymmetry have to be rooted in the microstructure of the
capital market.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

Asset pricing in a world with information asymmetry ( a market microstructure model)

A

• Easley and O’Hara (2004) develop a market microstructure model which
addresses the impact of information asymmetry on asset pricing.

• Building on a multi-asset noisy rational expectations framework,

• they assume two types of investors:
– an uninformed group receiving only public signals about assets and
– an informed group which receives additional private signals;

• where the total amount of signals is fixed.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

Easley and O’Hara (2004): Results

A
  • Uninformed investors can infer information from price, but only partially.
  • Thus, they end up holding different portfolios than informed investors.
  • As more investors get informed, information asymmetry is reduced,
  • prices become more informative and
  • the cost of capital is reduced.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

Summing up…

A

• Informationally efficient markets seem to leave little reason for financial
accounting from a valuation perspective:
– Information is already priced.
– Financial accounting seems to be important to motivate truthfully self-
reporting by managers (contracting).

• But, producing and evaluating financial accounting information is costly:
– It appears rational to form expectations on price, to engage in piggy-back
riding on information evaluation by informed traders.
– Doubtful whether informationally efficient markets can exist in equilibrium.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

Two types of investors:

A
  • Retail investors: rely on publicly available signals (eg. published by analysts)
  • Institutional investors: also have access to private signals (eg. from in- house research departments)