Midterm Flashcards
What is policy analysis?
Policy analysis is the application of theory and evidence to predict or evaluate the outcomes of alternative policies
- Focus of this course will be on quantitative methods for policy analysis, primarily cost-benefit analysis and related tools
- Policy analysis can use qualitative methods (e.g., interviews), but these are not covered in this course; this doesn’t mean that they aren’t valuable (there are certainly situations in which something other than CBA is the most appropriate tool), they’re simply not our focus here
What is the Informative role of policy analysis?
My questions often use the word “should”
Normative analysis, not simply positive analysis
-Does the policy make things more efficient? By how much?
-Does the policy make things more or less equitable? Who wins and loses, and by how much? How do we bring these issues together?
-“Should” is only part of the policy-making process (political feasibility, legal issues, etc.), but failing to answer the “should” question means creating policy blindly
Basic Analytical Framework
- Define the primary research question
Identify policies to be evaluated, and the measurable variables required to describe them
Specify one or more outcome variables and how they are to be measured
Note the difference between a “policy” and a “goal” - Decide who has standing
Standing: whose costs and benefits count?
E.g., should analysis of a project being considered by California government include benefits to everyone, or only benefits to California residents? - Choose a method of analysis
Cost-benefit analysis, cost-effectiveness analysis, etc.
Week 2 for CBA, weeks 5 and 7 for others - Predict the quantitative impacts of the policy
Empirical analysis guided by economic theory; may involve original empirical work or analysis of previous studies by others
Week 6 - Monetize (assign dollar values to) these impacts
Allows meaningful comparison of different impacts (common units of measurement)
Weeks 9 and 10 - Incorporate time pattern of impacts
Discount costs and benefits occurring at different points in time to make them comparable
Weeks 3 and 4 - Evaluate alternative policies using chosen criterion
E.g., compute and compare Net Present Value (NPV)
Week 2 for CBA, weeks 5 and 7 for other analyses - Address uncertainty with sensitivity analysis
Analysis often involves substantial uncertainty; how robust are the results to changes in the values used?
Weeks 11, 13
What are Challenges for effective analysis?
- Deciding whose benefits and costs count (assigning standing): What is your perspective (national, regional, etc.)?
- Selecting the portfolio of alternatives: Not just broad alternatives, but key details (when do they occur, etc.)
- Predicting quantitative impacts: The policies you analyze often haven’t occurred yet; how can you best predict what will happen?
- Valuing the impacts: What if there is no market?
- Extra complications: discounting over time, adjusting for social vs. private benefits and costs, adjusting for risk, etc.
- Performing sensitivity analysis: How many of the infinite possibilities do you present?
Different (wrong) perceptions about CBA
It’s political in nature
Promoted by Reagan, Bush, Clinton, Bush, Obama (see Cass Sunstein article, “The Stunning Triumph of Cost-Benefit Analysis”)
It ignores non-financial costs/benefits
This wouldn’t be CBA, but “revenue-expenditure analysis”
We wouldn’t need to “monetize the policy impacts” if we were only considering finances
Revenues ≠ social benefits. Expenditures ≠ social costs.
It can justify any government intervention
Only if all relevant costs and benefits are not included properly; e.g., politicians might use “constituency-support analysis”
At best, this ignores opportunity costs (“as long as somebody else pays, it’s free!”); at worst, counts them as benefits (“expenditures are good if they’re in my district!”)
Most (not all) criticisms of CBA apply to poorly done analysis, not CBA per se
Pareto Improvement
A policy creates a Pareto improvement (leads to a Pareto superior allocation) if it makes at least one person better off without making anyone worse off
Pareto Efficient
An allocation of goods is Pareto efficient if no change could make anyone better off without making someone else worse off
Another way of putting it: there are no mutually beneficial trades available (no Pareto improvements can be made)
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics
A Pareto Efficient Allocation emerges from trade if
All producers and consumers are perfect competitors (i.e., price takers, i.e., no market power), and;
A market exists for each and every commodity.
Why?
Price-taking consumers each buy a good until 𝑀𝐵=𝑃
Price-taking producers each producer a good until 𝑀𝐶=𝑃
Since consumers and producers have the same prices:
All consumers have the same marginal benefit of consumption (no efficiency gains by reallocating a given amount among consumers)
All producers have the same marginal cost of consumption (no efficiency gains by reallocating a given amount of production among producers)
Marginal benefit of consumption and marginal cost of production are equal (no efficiency gains by producing more or less of the good)
What are the Three primary justifications for public policy?
- Establishing institution framework
- Correcting market failure (the “well-functioning” caveat is not trivial)
- Promoting equity (an efficient allocation might be undesirably inequitable)
What is institutional Framework?
Government can make a major contribution to economic efficiency through its provision of an institutional infrastructure that enables the market system to function
Major example: legal system
What is Importance of institutional infrastructure?
Poor infrastructure can seriously hinder productive economic activity
A 1997 study found that average output per worker was nearly 6 times as high in countries with high-quality infrastructure as in those with low-quality infrastructure (corrupt government, weak property rights, etc.)
Example of bad infrastructure: a 2002 World Bank study found that Russian households paid $3 billion in bribes each year, mostly to education workers and police
Context: total income another $33 billion in bribes each year
Another example: a 2006 study found that, in Guatemala, it took roughly 4 years to collect on a significant debt
…when the collector was unambiguously in the right
Correcting market failure
- Market failure: a situation in which a free market fails to achieve economic efficiency
- Four main sources of market failure
1. Market power
2. Public goods
3. Externalities
4. Asymmetric information
Define Market Power
The standard competitive model assumes small buyers and sellers that take prices as given
If producers or consumers are large, they may instead account for the effect that their behavior has on prices (they are not price-takers)
E.g., for a monopolist, MPB ≠ MSB
As a result, the market does not produce the efficient level of output (where MSC = MSB)
Public Goods
Standard model requires that goods be excludable and rival in consumption (“private goods”)
A good is rival if each unit a person consumes reduces the amount available for others
A good is excludable if people who don’t pay for it can be prevented from consuming it (without preventing everyone from consuming it)
When this is not the case, private benefits and costs are not aligned with social benefits and costs
Pure public goods (non-rival, non-excludable): underprovision of good because individuals have incentive not to pay for good (can consume without paying; “free rider problem”)
Common resources (rival, non-excludable): overconsumption because MPC < MSC
Externalities
An externality occurs when a production or consumption decision has an effect on someone who is not involved in the transaction
Whether an externality is positive or negative, the outcome produced by the free market will be inefficient (possible exception: Coase Theorem)
Negative externality
a cost is imposed on a third party
Results in overconsumption because MPC < MSC
Positive externality
a third party receives benefits
Results in underconsumption because MPB < MSB
Asymmetric information
In some situations, relevant information is only available to one side of the market
Creates two mechanisms for market failure:
Adverse selection: not all products (or customers, workers, etc.) are identical, and asymmetric information about quality causes low-quality products to drive high-quality products out of the market
Moral hazard: when protected from the consequences of their behavior as the result of a transaction (e.g., acquiring insurance), people change their behavior in a way that is detrimental to the other party (e.g., insurer
Providing Equity
Correction of market failure is justified on the basis of efficiency: there are efficiency gains produced by government intervention
The other major rationale for government activity is equity, or fairness
Important note: efficiency and equity are two separate criteria (an outcome can be efficient but not equitable, or vice versa), but improvements in one may come at the expense of the other in practice
A challenge of dealing with equity issues is that there is no single notion of what “fairness” entails (equality of opportunity, equality of outcomes, commodity egalitarianism, etc.)
Government Intervention
Direct government intervention in a market can have positive or negative effects on efficiency
In the absence of a market failure, government intervention in a market reduces efficiency
If a market is efficient (total surplus is maximized) to begin with, any movement away from the competitive equilibrium must reduce total surplus
In the presence of a market failure, government intervention can be efficiency-improving
Important note: market failure (inefficiency) does not necessarily justify government intervention, just creates a situation in which intervention could be efficiency-improving
Economics and Ethics of CBA
Conceptual economic foundations for conducting cost-benefit analysis
Review: opportunity cost and marginal analysis
Review: consumer choice problem
Economic value (individually vs. collectively)
Social welfare
Ethical issues surrounding CBA
Opportunity cost
Opportunity cost: what is given up when taking an action or making a choice
Also called the marginal cost of that action/choice
Equal to the value of the best alternative that you’ve forgone by taking that action/making that choice
Includes all relevant costs
Explicit costs: actual monetary payments
Implicit costs: non-monetary costs (e.g., value of time)
Excludes irrelevant costs
Sunk costs: paid in the past, cannot be recovered
Fixed costs: unaffected by this particular action/decision
Marginal analysis
Decision rule for rational economic behavior:
MC = MB
MC: marginal cost, MB: marginal benefit
When you see “marginal”, think “additional” or “incremental”; has to do with “a little more” of something
“Rational” means “suits the decision maker’s interest” without assuming any particular motivations (e.g. selfishness, altruism, materialism, etc.)
In words: the optimal amount of any activity is that at which its MC is equal to its MB
For yes/no decisions, an action should be taken if MB > MC (if MB = MC, indifferent between options)
Review: consumer choice problem
Fundamental problem faced by consumers: choose the bundle of goods and services that maximizes utility (well-being, satisfaction, etc.), subject to the resources available
Two basic elements: preferences and budget
Consumer achieves maximum well-being by choosing the consumption bundle that gives the highest level of utility attainable given the budget constraint they face
Economic value of policies
A key goal of of policy analysis is to determine the costs and benefits of a specific policy
Before we think about the benefits and costs across everyone in society, let’s think about a particular individual first (then later we’ll “add up” across individuals)