IMF Theory Chapter 2 Flashcards

1
Q

Define financial market.

A

(Omega,F,P,(F_t)_t,S^0,S)

Fixed time horizon T in N.
1) Omega (all possible states of the world)
2) A sig-algebra F on Omega, representing all the ‘pertinent’-events, which means the ones we want to be able to give probability to. (If Omega is finite/countable, typically F=2^Omega)
3) Probability measure P on (Omega,F)
4) Filtration IF=(F_t)_t on (Omega,F,P) (information structure, where F_t=information available at time t) F_0={{},Omega} and F_T=F. (Omega,F,P,IF)=filtered prob. space
v) Financial assets:
- Non-risky asset: S^0={S^0_t : t int in [0,T]}, S^0_0=1, S^0t is F{t-1}-m-able i.e. (S^0_t)t predictable.
S^0
{t+1}=S^0_t*R_t for t in [0,T-1], R_t F_t-m-able
- d in N\0 risky assets w. price process S^i={S^i_t:t in [0,T-1]}. S^i_t pos. and F_t-m-able (S^i IF-adapted, not predictable)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

Define portfolio and wealth.

A

A portfolio is an IF-adapted process (η, Δ) with values in RxR^d.
More precisely, for any t in [0,T], η_t is the number of shares of the non-risky asset in the port., while Δ^i_t is the number of shares of the i-th risky asset in the portfolio at time t, for i in {1,..,d}.
The wealth associated to this portfolio at time t is given by
η_tS^0_t+Δ_tS_t,
where Δ_tS_t=Sum[Δ^i_tS^i_t ; i=1,..,d]

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Define consumption process.

A

For any portfolio, we define the associated consumption process c, by:
c_t:= -η_tS^0t - Δ_t*S_t+( η{t-1}S^0t + Δ{t-1}*S_t)
=( η_{t-1} - η_t , Δ_{t-1} - Δ_t ) * (S^0_t, S_t)^T
A positive c_t means that the investor consumed some of his wealth at t, while c_t<0, means that he injected cash into his portfolio at time t.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Define self-financing.

A

A portfolio (η, Δ) is self-financing if the associated consumption process is always 0.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q
Define A(IR^n)
(Script A).
A

A(IR^n):={IR^n-valued, IF-adapted processes}

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

Characterize portfolio.

A
A portfolio (η, Δ) can be characterized by the triplet (x,Δ,c) in IRxA(IR^n)xA(IR), where x is the initial capital of the portfolio.
Correspondence:
η_0 :=x - Δ_0*S_0
η_t=η_{t-1} - (Δ_t - Δ_{t-1})*S_t/S^0_t - c_t/S^0_t

or

η_t = x - Δ_0S_0 - Sum(Δ_t - Δ_{t-1})S_k/S^0_k + c_k/S^0_k ; k=1,..,t)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

Define the wealth process X^{x,Δ}

A

X^{x,Δ}_0:=x

X^{x,Δ}t:=X^{x,Δ}{t-1}+Δ_{t-1}(S_t-S_{t-1})+(X^{x,Δ}{t-1} - Δ{t-1}S_{t-1})*(S^0t-S^0{t-1})/S^0_{t-1}

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

Define discounted value.

A

For any process V, we denote its discounted value by

V~_t := V_t / S^0_t = V_t * d(0,t)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

State the discounted wealth process

A

X~^{x,Δ}t:=[X^{x,Δ}{t-1}+Δ_{t-1}(S_t-S_{t-1})+(X^{x,Δ}{t-1} - Δ{t-1}S_{t-1})(S^0t-S^0{t-1})/S^0{t-1}] / S^0_t
=…=X~^{x,Δ}
{t-1}+Δ_{t-1}
(S~t -S~{t-1})

It follows that

X~^{x,Δ}t = x + Sum( Δ_k * (S~{k+1} - S~_k) ; t=0,..,T )
=x + Int( Δ_s dS~_s ; [0,t] )

lecture 8

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

Define arbitrage opportunity.

A

An arbitrage opportunity is an investment strategy Δ in A(IR^d) s.t.: P(X^{0,Δ}_T >= 0)=1 and P(X^{0,Δ}_T > 0) > 0.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

State NA / AoA condition.

A

For all Δ in A(IR^d):

P(X^{0,Δ}_T >= 0)=1, then P(X^{0,Δ}_T = 0) =1

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

Consider the setting where T=1, d=1, and assume that Omega is finite.
State the equivalence conditions of NA.

A

pg 62

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

Define (IF,Q)-martingale.

Give an example under NA for a given finite prob space (Omega,F,Q).

A

(X_t)_{t=0,..,T} martingale if X is IF-adapted, and

i) E^Q[ |X_t| ] finite
ii) X_t = E^Q[ X_{t+1} | F_t ] Q-a.s.

Lect notes 8

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

Define risk-neutral measure.

A

A prob. measure Q on (Omega,F) is called a risk-neutral measure (or sometimes an equivalent martingale measure EMM) if:

i) Q~P
ii) S~ is an IR^d-valued martingale under Q.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

Super/-submarts ineq.

A

Super: E[M_t|F_{t-1}] leq M_{t-1}
Sub: opp.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

Define stopping time.

Characterize stopping time.

A

An IF-stopping time τ is a random variable taking values in IN s.t.
{τ leq t} in F_t

τ IN-valued stopping time iff {τ = t} in F_t for all t

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
17
Q

Define τ_{x,[x,inf)}

A

Notation for τ_{x,[x,inf)} := inf{ t in IN : X_t>=x }, which is an IF-stopping time.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
18
Q

Define stopped process.

A

Let Y be an IF-adapted process, and τ an IF-stopping time. The stopped process Y^τ is defined by:
Y^τ_t := Y_min(τ,t)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
19
Q

Define information available at time τ.

A

F_τ := { A in F | for all t in IN : A n {τ=t} in F_t }

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
20
Q

Let Y be IF-adapted and τ an IF-stopping time.

What are Y^τ and F_τ (mathematically)?

A

i) Y^τ is IF-adapted, F_τ is a sub-sig-alg. of F, and Y_τ is F_τ-mable
ii) If Y is an (IF,P)-mart. (/sub/supermart.), then so is Y^τ.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
21
Q

Define local (IF,P)-martingale

A

A process M is said to be an (IF,P)-local martingale if there exists a sequence (τ_n)_n of IF-stopping times s.t.

i) lim τ_n = inf (n->inf), P-a.s.
ii) M^{τ_n} is an (IF,P)-martingale for all n in IN.

(τ_n)_n is called a localizing sequence for the local mart. M.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
22
Q

Construct a local mart. from a mart.

A
M a IR^m-val. (IF,P)-mart. and φ in A(IR^m) BOUNDED! then
Y_t=Sum(  φ_k * (M_{k+1}-M_k) ; t=0,..,t-1 )
is an (IF,P)-local mart.

BTW: if Q risk-neutral measure, this proves that X~^{x,Δ} is an (IF,Q)-locla mart. for any self-financing port. (0,Δ).

pf: slide 2, lecture 9

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
23
Q

Give necessary and sufficient condition for a local martingale to be a martingale.

A

If M is a IR-valued (IF,P)-local mart. on a fixed time interval [0,T], for some integer T.
Then M is an (IF,P)-martingale if and only if E[M^-_T] < inf, where x^- := max(0,x).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
24
Q

State FTAP.

A

Fundamental theorem of asset pricing:
TFAE:
i) NA
ii) M(S) != {}, where M(S) is the set of risk-neutral measures on the market.

25
Q

d=T=1, Ω= {ω^u, ω^d}, IF={ { } }.

Find the set risk-neutral measures.

A

lecture 10

One-period binomial model:
If NA or 0

F=2^Ω }, S^0(ω) = (1, R)(ω) for all ω, S_0 > 0, S_1(ω) = uS_01{ω=ω^u}+dS_01{ω=ω^d}, 0

26
Q

Multinomial model:
d=1, Ω= {ω^u, ω^d}^T, F_0={ }, F_T=2^Ω,
F_t=σ( (ω_1,..,ω_s) : s in {1,..,t} ),
(R_t)_t, (u_t)_t, (d_t)_t all IF-adapted and s.t. R_t pos. and 0.
Describe the risky asset and state risk-neutral measure under conditions it exists.

A

lecture 10

27
Q

T=d=1, Ω= {ω^1, ω^2, ω^3}, F=2^Ω, IF= ( {{},Ω} , F), (p1,p2) in (0.1)^2 and
P({ω^1})=p1, P({ω^2}=p2, P({ω^3})=1-p1-p2.

S^0_0=1, S^0_1=R
S_1(ω)=u1S_01{ω=ω^1}+u2S_01{ω=ω^2}+u3S_01{ω=ω^3}

Is there a risk neutral measure? If so what is it?

A

lecture 11

28
Q

Define viable.

A

ξ payoff of an option with maturity T.

A price p in R for this option is said to be viable if buying or selling the option at this price does not create arbitrage opportunities in the market.
In other words, there does not exist Δ in A(IR^d) s.t
P(X^{p,Δ}_T - ξ >=0)=1 and P(X^{p,Δ}_T - ξ>0)>0
or
P(X^{p,Δ}_T + ξ >=0)=1 and P(X^{p,Δ}_T + ξ>0)>0
29
Q

Define to super-hedge, super-hedging price and sub-hedging price.

A

ξ payoff of an option with maturity T.

The price p allows the seller to super-hedge the payoff ξ if there exists Δ in A(IR^d) s.t.
P(X^{p,Δ}_T >= ξ)=1.

The super-hedging price of ξ is defined by:
p(ξ):=inf{p in IR : exists Δ in A(IR^d), P(X^{p,Δ}_T >= ξ)=1 }.

The sub-hedging price of ξ is defined as -p(-ξ) and verifies:
-p(-ξ):=sup{ p in IR ; exists Δ in A(IR^d), P(ξ >= X^{p,Δ}_T )=1 }.

30
Q

Define replicable.

A

The payoff ξ of an option with maturity T is said to be replicable if there exists a pair (x,Δ) in IRxA(IR^d) s.t.
P(X^{x,Δ}_T=ξ)=1.
Any such pair (x,Δ) is called a replicating strategy for ξ.

31
Q

Related viable prices with (super-/sub-)hedging prices.

A

p(ξ) is the largest possible viable price for the option with payoff ξ (it is not clear if it is one however).
Symetrically, -p(-ξ) is the lowest possible viable price.
In other words, the set of viable prices for ξ is contained in [-p(-ξ),p(ξ)].
Furthermore, the set of viable prices is either an interval or a singleton.

32
Q

State the properties of p(ξ)

super-hedging price

A

i) p is sublinear, ie p(ξ1)+p(ξ2)>=p(ξ1+ξ2)
ii) If P(ξ1>=ξ2)=1, then p(ξ1)>=p(ξ2)
iii) p is positively homogeneous, that for any λ>0:
p(λξ)=λp(ξ)
iv) We have p(0)=0 and p(ξ) >= -p(-ξ).

33
Q

Define IL_S(IR,F_T).

A

IL_S(IR,F_T) := { X ; X F_T-mable, IR-valued and for all Q in M(S): E^Q[|X|] < inf }

34
Q

State the result of replicability, initial capital and “explicit” formula for p(ξ).

Generalize the result.

A

Let ξ be a replicable payoff, with some replicating strategy (x^0,Δ^0) in IRxA(IR^d). Then
x^0=p(ξ)= -p(-ξ)=inf{ p in IR ; exists Δ in A(IR^d), P(X^{p,Δ}_T=ξ)=1 }.
In particular, all the replicating strategies for ξ have the same initial capital.
In addition, if NA holds and (d(0,T)ξ)^- in IL_S(IR,F_T), then
p(ξ)=E^Q[d(0,T)
ξ] for all Q in M(S).

Now to argue why p_t(ξ)=E^Q[d(t,T)*ξ | F_t], where p_t(ξ) is the time value of the option with replicable payoff ξ….

Since ξ is replicable, there is a self-financing portfolio X^{x,Δ} s.t. P(X^{x,Δ}_T=ξ)=1.
By the no-dominance principle therefore:
P(X^{x^0,Δ^0}_t=p_t(ξ))=1 for all t in [0,T], i.e. X^{x^0,Δ^0}_t=p_t(ξ) P-a.s.
Whenever (d(0,T)*ξ)^- in IL_S(IR,F_T), NA holds and X~^{x^0,Δ^0} is an (IF,Q)-mart. for any Q in M(S), we have:
d(0,t)*p_t(ξ)=p~_t(ξ)=X~^{x^0,Δ^0}=E^Q[ X~^{x^0,Δ^0}_T | F_t ]
=E^Q[ d(0,T)*ξ | F_t ]
iff
p_t(ξ)=E^Q[ d(0,T)*ξ/d(0,t) | F_t ]=E^Q[ d(t,T)*ξ | F_t ]
35
Q

Value forward agreements using measure theoretic probability theory.

A

lecture 12, slide 8
S_t-K*B(t,T)
This uses proposition from end of previous lecture 11

36
Q

Show that payoffs in the one period binomial model with two outcomes are replicable.

A

P(X^{x,Δ}_1=ξ)=1
iff X^{x,Δ}_1(ω^u)=ξ(ω^u), X^{x,Δ}_1(ω^d)=ξ(ω^d)
iff ΔuS_0+(x-ΔS_0)R=ξ(ω^u), ΔdS_0+(x-ΔS_0)R=ξ(ω^d)
iff Δ=[ξ(ω^u)-ξ(ω^d)] / [(u-d)S_0] (=[ξ(ω^u)-ξ(ω^d)] / [S_1(ω^u)-S_1(ω^d)], x=1/R(qξ(ω^u)-(1-q)ξ(ω^d)), where q=(R-d)/(u-d)

37
Q

Show that the multi-period binomial model is replicable..

A

lecture 12, slide 3

38
Q

Find the replicating strategy for the lookback call option on slide 5, lecture 12.

A

.

39
Q

Find a replicating strategy of the one-period trinomial model.

Show that only one solution exists his his equation.

A

lecture 12, slide 7

40
Q

State the superhedging duality theorem.

A

If (NA) holds and ξ payoff s.t. (d(0,T)ξ)^- in IL_S(IR,F_T).
Then:
p(ξ)=sup {E^Q[d(0,T)
ξ] ; Q in M(S) }
-p(-ξ)=inf {E^Q[d(0,T)ξ] ; Q in M(S) }
If in addition p(ξ) finite, then there is a Δ
in A(IR^d) s.t. P(X^{p(ξ),Δ*}_T>=ξ)=1. Furthermore, the set of viable prices is the relative interior of [-p(-ξ),p(ξ)], and p(ξ)=-p(-ξ) if and only if ξ is replicable.

Remark: The previous theorem shows us that whenever M(S) is a singleton, all payoffs are replicable. In this case, we say that the financial market is complete. The converse is true and this constitues the 2nd FTAP.

41
Q

Define completeness of a financial market.

A

A financial market is said to be complete if all contingent claims ξ with (d(0,T)*ξ)^- in IL_S(IR,F_T), s.t. p(ξ) is finite, are replicable.

Incomplete=not complete

42
Q

Characterize completeness when NA holds.

A

If (NA) holds, then the financial market is complete iff

M(S) is a singleton.

43
Q

Three parts of the FTAP proof.

A

i) show enough to consider 1-period models, by introducing local arbitrage opportunities.
ii) Characterize local arbitrage opportunities in more “geometric” terms UPDATE?? What does he mean
iii) Use Hahn-Banach theorem to construct risk-neutral measure in one-period model

44
Q

Define local arbitrage.

A

Let Q be equivalent to P, and let t be in {1,..,T}.
A t-local arbitrage is a random variable ξ, IR-valued and F_{t-1}-mable, s.t. Q[ ξ(S~t-S~{t-1}) >= 0 ] =1
and Q[ ξ
(S~t-S~{t-1}) > 0 ] >0.

Interpretation: A t-local arbitrage opportunity is a specific Δ in A(IR^d) s.t. Δ_k=0 for k in {0,..,T-1}{t-1}.
In this case X~^{0,Δ}=Δ_{t-1}*(S~t-S~{t-1})
Thus it is an arbitrage between t-1 and t.

45
Q

State NA_{loc}.

A

The financial market has no local arbitrage opportunities.
i.e.
for all Q~P and t in {1,..,T}:
If Q[ ξ(S~t-S~{t-1}) >= 0 ] = 1 for some ξ in L^0(IR,F_{t-1}),
then Q[ ξ
(S~t-S~{t-1}) = 0 ] = 1

46
Q

Define K^0(IR,F_t,Q).

A

We can assume that S~t-S~{t-1} is bounded by defining
δ_t:=(S~t-S~{t-1})/(1+||S~t-S~{t-1}||), which is IF-adapted.
K^0(IR,F_t,Q):={ X in L^0(IR,F_t) : exists ξ in L^0(IR^d,F_t-1), Q(ξ*δ_t >= X) =1 }

Intuition: Forgetting division by 1+||S~t-S~{t-1}|| in δ_t, elements of K^0 are exactly the payoffs at time t, which can be super-replicated by trading with 0 initial capital between t-1 and t.

47
Q

Characterize NA_{loc}

A

NA and NA_{loc} are equivalent.

Also:
For all t in {1,..,T} and Q~P
NA_t iff K^0(IR,F_t,Q) n L^0_+(IR,F_t,Q)={0}.

Second characterization on slide 7 of lecture 14.

Also:
Fix t in {1,..,T} and some Q~P. Then
NA_t iff there exists a Z in L^inf(IR,F_t,Q) s.t.
Q(Z>0)=1 and E^Q[ Z*(S~t-S~{t-1}) | F_{t-1} ] =0.

48
Q

What topological property does K^0 have?

A

Let NA_t for some t hold, then for any A~P:

K^0(IR,F_t,Q) is closed in Q-probability.

49
Q
Define N(IR^d,F_{t-1},Q) and N^⊥(IR^d,F_{t-1},Q).
State relation between N^⊥(IR^d,F_{t-1},Q) and L^0(IR^d,F_{t-1})
A

For all t in {1,..,T}, all Q~P and all ξL^0(IR^d,F_{t-1}), there exists a bar(ξ) in N^⊥(IR^d,F_{t-1},Q), s.t.
Q[ ξ * δ_t = bar(ξ) * δ_t ]=1.
Lecture 13, slide 7

50
Q

Fix t in {0,..T} and Q~P. Let (X_n)_n sequence of r.v.s in L^0 s.t. Q(liminf ||X_n|| finite)=1.
Then?

A

There is a sequence of IN-valed r.v.s (τ_n)n and an r.v. X in L^0 s.t. Q( lim X{τ_n} = X )=1

(lim w.r.t. n->inf)

51
Q

If time add version of Hahn-Banach..

A

.

52
Q

State the Stricker-Yan theorem.

A

Let Q be a prob. measure on (Ω,F) and G s.s. F a σ-alg.. Let C be a closed convex cone of L^1(IR,G,Q) s.t.
L^1- (IR,G,Q) s.s. C and C n L^1+(IR,G,Q)={0}.
Then there exists a Z in L^inf_+(IR,G,Q) s.t. Q(Z>0)=1, and E^Q[Y*Z] non-pos. for all Y in C.

53
Q

Define calligraphic K^2(IR,F_T,P) and state a topological property.

A

Set of M in L^0(IR,F_T) s.t. there exists Δ in A(IR^d) s.t. X~^{0,Δ}_T is a.s. greater or equal to M

54
Q

Let NA hold, assume that S~t in L^2(IR^d,F_t,P) for all t in {0,..T}, that (d(0,T)ξ)^- in L_S(IR,F_T), and that p(ξ)=-p(-ξ). Let Q be an element of M(S) with bounded density. Then P(X_T^{p(ξ),Δ}=ξ)=1 for any Δ in A(IR^d) s.t. Δ_t in cal(S)t(V,Q), t in {0,..,T-1} where
V_T:=d(0,T)ξ, V_t:=E^Q[V
{t+1}|F_t] and cal(S)t(V,Q) is the set of F_t-mable r.v.s which are IR^d-valued and satisfy:
Δ_t * E^Q[(S~
{t+1}-S~t)(S~^1{t+1}-S~^i_t)|F_t]=E^Q[V
{t+1}(S~^i_{t+1}-S~_t)|F_t] for all i in {1,..,d}.

Use this to find a replicating strategy in the binomial market.

A

.

55
Q

Define the quadratic error of hedging a contingent claim.

A
v_q(x,ξ):=inf {E^Q[(d(0,T)ξ-X~^{x,Δ}_T)^2] : Δ in A_2(IR)},
where A_2(IR) is the subset of A(IR) s.t. investment strategies are square integrable.
56
Q

State the non-degeneracy condition in the context of mean-variance hedging.

Give an equivalent condition.

A

There exists δ in (0,1) s.t. for all t in {1,..,T} the inequality:
(E^P[S~t-S~{t-1} | F_{t-1} ] )^2 leq δ * E^P[(S~t-S~{t-1})^2| F_{t-1}] holds.

BTW: We also assume S~ in L^2 before

alpha_t := E[S~t - S~{t+1} | F_{t-1}] / E[(S~t - S~{t+1})^2 | F_{t-1}] (if denominator is 0 then def =0) is finite for all t and small omega.

57
Q

Under which conditions is there a strategy s.t. the quadratic error of hedging a contingent claim is attained?

How can we get such a Δ(x,ξ)?

A

Let ND hold, then for ξ s.t. d(0,T)ξ in L^2(IR,F_T,P) and any x in R there exists a Δ(x,ξ) in A_2(IR) s.t.
V_q(x,ξ)=E^P[(d(0,T)ξ-X~^{x,Δ(x,ξ)}_T)^2].

By a backward induction algorithm:
define β_t := E^P[(S~t-S~{t-1
)Prod(1-β_j(S~j-S~{j-1}))|F_{t-1}] / E^P[(S~t-S~{t-1})^2Prod(1-β_j(S~j-S~{j-1}))^2|F_{t-1}]β
ρ_t(ξ):=E^P[d(0,T)ξ(S~t-S~{t-1})Prod(1-β_j(S~j-S~{j-1})|F_{t-1}]/E^P[d(0,T)ξ(S~t-S~{t-1})^2Prod(1-β_j(S~j-S~{j-1})^2|F_{t-1}]
All Prod’s for j=t+1,..,T

Then (if ND), Δ(x,ξ)=ρ_{t+1}(ξ)-β_{t+1}X~^{x,Δ(x,ξ)}_t

58
Q

Define the r.v. Z~ and state its properties (context quadratic hedging).

A
Lemma:
Z~ := Prod( (1-β_j*(S~_j - S~_{j-1} )) ; j=1,..,T )
* Z~ in L^2
* E[Z~] in [0,1]
* E[Z~]=0 iff Z~=0 a.s.
59
Q

State the proposition about the variance-optimal viable prices.

A

Let u_q(chi) = inf_{x in R} v_q(x, chi)
If ND holds:
Z~=0 a.s. then u_q(chi) = E[(d(0,T)chi - Sum[rho_j(S~j - S~{j-1}) Prod( (1-beta~_k(S~_k - S~{k-1}) : k=j+1,..T)] and inf. is attained for all x in R.
Z~ =/= 0 a.s., then
u_q(chi) = v_q(p_q(chi),chi) = - E[Z~
d(0,T)chi]^2 / E[Z~] + above term,
where p_q(chi) := E[Z~/E[Z~]
d(0,T)*chi].
Furthermore, in this case P~ exists and its density D~ is given by D~ = Z~ / E[Z~].