Gedächtnisprotokolle Flashcards

1
Q

State the utility maximization problem.

A

max x≥0 u(x) s.t. px ≤ w

Want to maximise the utility of our consumption bundle given our budget constraint that the price of our consumption cannot exceed wealth.

We know that the UMP has a solution when the prices are strictly positive (p»0) and our utility function is continuous.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

State and explain the FOC to the UMP.

A

Since the UMP is a constrained problemm we use the Langragian to derive the FOC

L= u(x) – λ [p * x-w]

1) Partial derivative wrt xi
δL/δxi = δ u(x) / δ xi – λ pi = 0

rearranged to: δ u(x)/ δxi = λpi

  • gives us the marginal utility of consumption
  • price of the good scaled by the multiplier, representing the marginal cost of spending one more unit of currency on the good
  • shadow price of langragian

2) Partial derivative wrt λ
λ = -(px-w) = 0

  • ensures that the budget constraint is binding: it implies that p * x=w and confirms our assumption.
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

How do we get from the Marshallian demand to the indirect utility?

A
  • Indirect utility is the utility of the optimal consumption bundle given our constraints by prices and wealth.
  • We can derive the indirect utility by plugging in the marhsallian demand into our utility function: u(x(p,w))
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

How can we recover the Marshallian demand from the indirect utility?

A

Roy’s Identity:
x(p,w)= - ∇p v(p,w)/ ∇w v(p,w)

It tells us how demand of good l responds to changes in prices of good l AFTER adjusting for the consumers wealth - holding u constant.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

State the cost minimization problem.

A

min wz s.t. f(z) ≥ q

Minimize the cost of production - subject to productive feasibility.

Result of cost minimization problem: conditional factor demand correspondence z(w,q)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

State FOC and SOC to Cost Minimization Problem.

A

CMP: min wz st F(z) ≥ q

L= wi zi - f(z)-q

FOC wi- λδf(z)/δzi

Rearrange to wi = λδf(z)/δzi

= cost wi of using an additional unit of input = the value of the output produced by that additional unit of input (the marginal product of input i times the shadow price λ).

SOC = second partial derivative must be larger or equal to 0

then objective function must be convex

for multiple variables the determinant of the bordered hessian must be positive semidefinite

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

Interpreting a hessian further

A

For a more accurate interpretation, one would need to examine the signs of the determinants of all the leading principal minors of the bordered Hessian matrix, and not just the determinant of the entire matrix.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

SOC Max Problem

A
  • ≤0
  • concave in x
  • H: negative semidefinite
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

SOC Min Problem

A
  • ≥ 0
  • convex in x
  • H: positive semidefinite
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

What do we have to assume for the cost min problem?

A

Problem should be well defined
1. Convex cost function with respect to input choices. This means that the cost increases at an increasing rate as you use more inputs, reflecting the principle of diminishing returns.
2. Well-Behaved Production Function: The production function f(z) is typically assumed to be quasi-concave and displays non-decreasing returns to scale up to a point
3. No Externalities?

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Properties of production function

A
  • non-decreasingin all inputs
  • If k=1, the function has constant returns to scale.
  • If k>1, it exhibits increasing returns to scale.
  • If k<1, it shows decreasing returns to scale.
  • concave in inputs = diminishing marginal returns
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

State and explain Shephard’s Lemma. What does it give us?

A

Case of deriving h(p,u) from e(p,u)
1. we know that e(p,u) = p h(p,u), we take the derivative of this wrt p and use the product rule for doing that
2. the result includes the FOC from the EMP problem which are per definiton = 0
3. we know that utility is held constant so the change in utility from a change in price = 0, ergo we dont need to worry about utility further
4. we can take the FOC from the EMP and rearrange it for the p
5. plugging the result from EMP for p into our partial derivative of e(p,u) wrt p then shepherds lemma is the result
6. here we also see the so-called indirect and direct effect- the direct effect is the second term which remains in the shepherds lemma but the first term falls away since the result is zero already by definition from the FOC

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

State and explain Hotelling’s Lemma. What does it give us?

A

Not the envelope theorem version:

  • connects profit maximization + supply function
  • follows from duality theorem
  • it says that the change in profits from a change in price is proportional to the quantity produced
  • If the supply function is single valued, then the gradient of the profit function wrt p gives us the supply at these prices

∇ π(p) = δπ(p) / δp = y * (p)

Proof:

  • function g(p) is maximised by y * at p

g(p) = π(p) - p y *

  • How would max value change if p changes? Just take partial derivative of the function above and rearrange so that ∇ π(p) = δπ(p) / δp = y * (p)
How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

State and explain the Envelope Theorem. When is which term equal to zero? Why? Tell us about direct and indirect effects.

A

1. Optimization Problem Set U
You have an objective function, f(x,α) that you want to maximize by choosing x subject to constraint g(x,α)=0

2. Langrangrian and FOC
L= f(x,α)- λg(x,α)-0 and FOC: δα/δx= δf(x,α)/ δx - λ δg(x,α)/ δx = 0 AND δα/δx= -g(x,α)=0 —> x(α)

3. Optimal Value Function v(α) is max value of objective function f(x,α) and we found best x(α)

4. Differentiate the value function- here envelope theorem comes in!
How does v(α) change when α changes? So we differentiate v(α) at α!

5. Applying Envelope Theorem
When differentiating v(α), the term involving δx/δα drops out bc of FOC - only the partial derivative of objective
function wrt δ remains = the way that v(α) changes as α changes does not depend on how x adjusts to α

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

State and explain a Walrasian equilibrium. What is a Walrasian equilibrium? When does it hold?

A

In a private ownership economy, an allocaton and a price vector consitute a WE when

1) firms maximize profits
2) consumer maximize their utility subject to their budget constraint that the value of their consumption cannot exceed their earnings from their endowments (p ω) and the sum of profits from firm shares they get which depend on firms profit
3) market clears that not more can be consumed as endowed and produced

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

Tell us about desirability. When does it hold?

A

Laws of desirability
1) monotonicity: if you have strictly more of x than y than x is preferred over y
2) strict monotonicity: if you have at least as much of x than y than x is preferred over y
3) LNS: in every distance epsilon to x there will be another x’ which is more preferred

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
17
Q

Aggregate demand, &aggregate wealth

A
  • AD depends on consumer’s wealth levels and not only on AW
  • we can work with AD as a function of AW IF
    1. individual demand changes from any redistribution must cancel out
    2. wealth expansion lines are parallel straight lines
    3. all consumers have identical preferences
18
Q

Gorman Form

A

GF is needed condition to exhibit parallel straight wealth expansion paths (necessary for AW to be a function of AD):
Preferences admit indirect utility functions of the Gorman Form with the coefficients on wi for every consumer:

That is
vi (p,wi) = ai(p) + b(p)wi

19
Q

State the profit maximization problem (verbally + writing it down).

A

max py s.t. F(y)≥0

PMP is maximising the revenue (price vector times production plan y) subject to production technology constraints (the production set Y and transformation function F).

20
Q

State the profit maximization problem for the one output and n input case. What has to hold for y?

A

Single output case:
max π(p) = p f(z) - w z

y = f(x)

21
Q

What are the FOCs in the Profit Maximization Problem? Explain both sides of the equation.

A

PMP is an unconstrained problem = no Langrangian

δπ/δz = p δf(z)/δzi - wi = 0
p δf(z)/δzi = wi, whereas wi is the factor price/marginal cost of input = marginal product times price and the left side is the marginal product times the price

22
Q

Give the SOC to the PMP

A

The second partial derivative should be smaller or equal to 0 and concave in x. The determinant of the bordered Hessian is negative semidefinite.

23
Q

What is the shape of the production function? Quasiconcave or concave? Why?

A
24
Q

Describe a quasiconcave function. What is the definition of quasiconcavity?

A

For every two bundles x,y e X, the utility of consuming the convex combination of these two bundles u(αx + 1-α)y), is weakly higher the the minimal utility from consuming each bundle seperately, min {u(x); u(y)} or more compactly:

u(αx+(1-α)y) ≥ min {u(x), u(y)}

Graphically:
* Starting from bundles x and y, with associated utility levels u(x) and u(y), respectively, we can construct a convex combination of the two bundles
* if the utility that the consumer derives from conming this convex combination is larger than consuming the bundle associated with the lowest utility level (in this case y), we say this individual utility function satisfies quasi-concavity

25
Q

Strict quasi-concavity

A

u(.) satsifies strict quasi-concavity if for every two bundles x,y e X the utility of consuming its convex combination u(αx+(1-α)y), where 0 < α < 1 is STRICTLY higher than the minimal utility from consuming wach bundle seperately.

Hence the utility function that yields the indifference curve in the fig satisfies strict quasi-concavity.

26
Q

Concavity and Quasi-Concavity

A

Concavity = Quasi-concavity
Quasi-concavity ≠ Concavity

Quasi-concavity is a weaker condition than concavity.

Concave u(.) implies:
* for an increase in the consumption bundle, the increase in utility is smaller as we move away from the origin = diminishing marginal utility

27
Q

Draw a convex upper contour set. What would be the upper contour set in the profit max case, is it convex? How does it compare to cost min?

A

An upper contour set of a function at a level c consists of all points x such that the function value at x is greater than or equal to c. For a profit function, this would represent all combinations of variables (like prices, output levels, and input quantities) that yield profit at least as high as c.

–> it would be convex

Cost Min:

  • also convex
  • If the cost function is convex, these upper contour sets are also convex.
  • This implies that any weighted average of two costly strategies will not be less costly, supporting the idea that the minimum cost solution is stable and unique under convexity assumptions.
28
Q

What shape does the utility function have in the UMP?

A

Quasi concave
IF
A utility function is quasiconcave if, for any two consumption bundles x and y and for any λ in the interval [0,1], the utility of the convex combination is at least as great as the minimum utility of the individual bundles.

Quasiconcavity is a weaker condition than concavity but still sufficient to ensure that preferences represented by the utility function are monotonic and that indifference curves are convex towards the origin. This condition supports the existence of a well-defined demand function and guarantees that consumer choices are consistent (no preference cycles).

Concave
IF
the second derivative (if differentiable) is negative, or if the function exhibits diminishing marginal utility, which means that as a consumer consumes more of a good, the additional satisfaction (utility) derived from each additional unit decreases.

This shape reflects risk aversion and the principle of diminishing marginal returns in consumption. It ensures that the utility function yields a unique optimal solution for consumption choices, given budget constraints.

29
Q

What is the result of the UMP?

A

Marshallian demand x(p,w)

30
Q

What does the indirect utility function tell us?

A

utility of the optimal consumption bundle x(p,w)
v(p,w) = u(x(p,w))

  1. nonincreasing in p, nondecreasing in w
  2. H(0) in (p,w)
  3. Quasi-convex in p
  4. continuous at all p»0, w>0
31
Q

From the indirect utility function, how do we get the expenditure function? Write down the identity.

A

v(p,e(p,u)) = u
e(p,v(p,u))= w

32
Q

Why can we invert the indirect utility function to get the expenditure function if there is local non-satiation?

A

1. Utility Maximization and Cost Minimization: Local non-satiation implies that there is always an incentive to consume more, which prevents satiation points where additional consumption does not increase utility. This property ensures that the maximization problem (for the indirect utility function) and the minimization problem (for the expenditure function) have solutions that are not bounded by the limits of utility levels.

2. Strict Monotonicity: Due to LNS, the utility function is strictly increasing in consumption, which means that more money (given constant prices) always allows for higher utility. This strict monotonicity ensures that the expenditure function, which identifies the least cost needed to achieve particular utility levels, is also strictly increasing in utility levels.

3. Invertibility: With LNS ensuring that more income always results in higher utility, the mapping from income levels to utility levels provided by the indirect utility function is one-to-one and onto within the economic domain of interest. This bijective (one-to-one and onto) relationship between v(p,w) and w for fixed p when utility is varied implies that we can invert the indirect utility function to find the expenditure function.

33
Q

What can we learn from the expenditure function about how Hicksian demand reacts to prices?

A

Sensitivity to prices from the partial derivative: If the derivative is high, small changes in the price of the good lead to large changes in the expenditure required to maintain the same utility, reflecting a high sensitivity of demand for this good.

Substitution effects: Because the expenditure function is calculated holding utility constant, the changes in demand reflect pure substitution effects—how consumers substitute between goods as prices change, without the income effect complicating their consumption choices

34
Q

Under what conditions does Walras’ Law hold?

A

Value of Excess Demand needs to be 0.

Conditions for WL

  1. Competitive Markets (many buyers, many sellers, no monopol)
  2. Price-Taking behavior (consumers max u, firms max profits)
  3. Rational Agents
  4. No Externalities
  5. Flexible prices (react to demand/supply)
  6. Complete markets = complete information
35
Q

What is an example of a utility representing preferences of the Gorman form?

A

It allows for straightforward aggregation of individual preferences into a representative consumer’s utility function.

Example would be:

36
Q

What happens if preferences are not convex with Walras’ Law?

A

Convexity is crucial - if non-convexity, then

  • multiple equilibria
  • discontinious demand functions
  • existence of equilbirium
  • value of excess demands = 0 not given
37
Q

When is profit max not possible?

A
  • zero economic profits
  • regulated industries
  • non-profit objective
  • complete information
  • rational decision making
38
Q

What is the result of profit max?

A

supply function y(p) optimal choice of outputs as a function of prices

39
Q

State the utility maximization problem.

A

max u(x) s.t. px ≤ w

40
Q

How are EMP and UMP related? When are they equivalent?

A

Yes, their dual relation is the cornerstone of consumer theory.

  • rational preference
  • preferences are continuous and monotone
  • utility is quasiconcave
  • positive prices
41
Q

Proof Roys Identity

A