Competition and Differentiation Flashcards
“Monopoly” refers, strictly, to a situation where
there is a single firm (or producer) in a market. The analysis of monopolies is more generally useful for understanding situations when firms have substantial pricing power: that is, the ability to set prices above cost without meaningful competitive retaliation.
In a perfectly competitive market, price typically falls to
where firms earn zero profits (that is, prices equal marginal costs).
monopolists typically price above
marginal cost. The reason is that a monopolist has the ability to set prices above cost without meaningful competitive retaliation.
Optimal pricing requires that firms price where
Marginal Revenue = Marginal Cost.
In a competitive market, the marginal revenue curve is the same as the demand curve. For a monopolist, the marginal revenue curve is___
lower than the demand curve. The marginal revenue that a monopolist generates by lowering its price reflects both the gain from attracting new customers (the “volume” effect) and the loss from lowering prices to existing or inframarginal customers (the “price” effect).
Just as a monopoly has power to raise prices, a buyer can have power to___
to reduce prices if it is the sole buyer in the market.
The analysis of monopoly pricing rests on the assumption that the firm charges the same price for every unit of the good, to every customer. In practice, firms are often able to “price discriminate” – that is, ___
charge different prices to different consumers, or set different prices for different units of a product.
Perfect (or first-degree) price discrimination involves
setting a different price for each consumer, or for each unit of the product. Perfect price discrimination eliminates deadweight loss and consumer surplus, and the producer captures all of the value.
Two-part tariffs involve firms setting ___
a per-unit price for a product (sometimes equal to $0) and charging a fixed fee to capture additional surplus. Two-part tariffs are an effective (and relatively easy) way for firms to price discriminate.
Firms charging different prices based on observable characteristics of consumers: example
e.g., whether the consumer is a student or senior
firms relying on self-selection to price discriminate: example
For example, firms can create separate versions of a product (business class versus coach for an airline) or offer discounts to consumers who buy in bulk.
In order to price discriminate, a firm must be able to
prevent buyers with high WTP from purchasing at the lower prices. If consumers are indistinguishable, this can be challenging. Price discrimination could also be prevented by competition from other firms, or if customers with low WTP could purchase the product and resell it to customers with higher WTP.
Price bundling is another way for firms to effectively price discriminate. Price bundling is more effective when
consumers’ preferences for the products are heterogeneous.
“Vertical” differentiation occurs when firms differ
in attributes that all customers value similarly – that is, when some firms produce a version of the product that is perceived as “better” by all customers, or when firms differentiate by lowering prices.
Horizontal” differentiation occurs when firms differ in
attributes that different customers value differently (e.g., location, color, etc). If firms are horizontally differentiated, some customers will prefer a product from one firm and others will prefer the product from another.