8. Oligopolistic Markets, Classical Duopolistic Models (Bertrand, Cournot, Stackelberg) Flashcards
Types of oligopolistic models
Models can be:
.
1. Collusive (e.g. cartel)
.
- Competitive: no collusion (Bertrand, Cournot, Stackelberg).
Simultaneous models (Bertrand, Cournot).
Sequential models (Stackelberg).
.
Key variables:
Prices adopted by each company (Bertrand)
Quantities offered by each company (Cournot, Stackelberg)
Oligopolistic models: Bertrand model
Bertrand 1822-1900
- Sequential decisions:
Decision on quantities: Quantity leadership (Stackelberg)
Decisions on prices: Price leadership
. - Simultaneous decisions:
Decision on quantities: Quantity choice (Cournot)
Decisions on prices: Price choice (Bertrand)
. - Collusion
Decision on quantities: Quantity joint decision
Decisions on prices: Price joint decision
Bertrand model
The Bertrand (1883) model analyzes firms’ behavior under conditions of oligopoly, adopting price as the focal strategic variable
In its simplest form, it is based on the following assumptions:
Only 2 companies: duopolistic competition
No potential entrants (closed markets)
Homogenous good
Perfect rationality
Perfect information
Same cost function (same technology) with MC=AC=c
Only 1 strategic variable: price
Price is decided simultaneously
.
Essentially, two identical, perfectly rational and perfectly informed firms i and j compete by simultaneously choosing price.
Consumers, who are also perfectly rational and perfectly informed, demand the good from the company with the lowest price.
Continued: What are the options for firm i? If i sets a price:
What are the options for firm i? If i sets a price:
.
- Lower than j, it captures the entire market demand
- Equal to j, it shares the market demand with j
- Greater than j, it has a null market demand (consumers demand the good from j)
.
The assumed cost function is: TC=c.q
.
This way:
Fixed costs are zero:
Average Cost (AC) and Marginal Cost (MC) coincide:
MC= row TC/row q=c ; AC= TC/q=c
Thus profit will be:
pi=(p-AC)q OR
pi=(p-c)q
.
i and j choose their price in order to maximize profits
.
Under our cost assumptions, profit functions are:
.(see presentation)
The game is simultaneous and competitive (each company tries to maximize its own profit)
Bertrand model - equilibrium
Nash equilibrium:
Couple of strategies where none of the players find it convenient to change strategy given the other’s strategy
No one can unilaterally change its position and improve its situation
Each company’s price maximizes profits given the other’s choice
.
It is possible to demonstrate that in the Nash equilibrium each firm chooses a price equal to c:
pi=pj=c
In this case, none of the two companies has an incentive to change its choice, given the other’s choice.
Price higher than c: loss of the entire demand
Price lower than c: the firms makes losses instead of profits
.
Given the market conditions, firms are identical and the game is symmetric; the reasoning developed for one player is perfectly applicable to the other
Cont
As long as either of the two firms sets a price higher than c, there is no equilibrium. The firm setting p > c always has an incentive to lower the price to the point it is infinitesimally lower than the price charged by the other firm, in order to capture the whole demand.
.
Each firm has always the incentive to revise its price decision, unless the price for both firms is equal to c=MC=AC
Bertrand model - critique
In reality, most industries with only two competitors seem to make extra profits.
Why?
.
Extra: Bertrand model (Pg 39)
Assumptions:
Assuming a linear cost function TC=c*y
The two firms choose a price in order to maximize profits:
The game is not cooperative: each firm maximizes its own profit.
The Bertrand’smodel solution is a Nash equilibrium: no one can unilaterally change its position and improve its situation. Each company’s price maximizes the profit, given the other’s choice.
It is possible to demonstrate that in the Nash equilibrium each firm chooses a price equal to its marginal costs. Pi=Pj=c
Firms cannot set different prices between each other and greater than c. Price cannot be lower than c, otherwise it would make losses instead of profits. Given the market conditions, firms are identical and the game is symmetric. The reasoning developed for one player is perfectly applicable to the other.
We can analyze three cases:
We can analyze three cases:
1. Pi> Pj>c
In this case, firms set different prices and higher than the marginal cost. Firm i has null demand, while j captures the entire market demand and makes extra-profits. This solution is not a Nash equilibrium, i finds convenient to reduce the price in order to make extra- profits. This situation goes on until the equilibrium.
.
2. Pi> Pj = c
In this case, firms set a different price and equal to the marginal cost. For both the firms the profit is null and they have an incentive to deviate from their choices. The firm i has null demand that is an incentive to reduce the price. The firm j has a null extra-profit, thus it has an incentive to raise the price until it is only a bit lower thanthe competitor’s price in order to capture the entire market.
.
3.Pi = Pj > c
In this case, they both gain extra-profits but we assume that they are competing and not colluding. Therefore, they will set a lower price in order to get the entire market instead of sharing.
.
Each company has always the incentive to revise its price decision unless the price for both companies is equal to the marginal cost. The equilibrium is the following:
This is a Nash equilibrium: none of the two companies has an incentive to change its choice, given the other’s choice. If the price is higher than the marginal cost, the company loses the entire demand.
If the price is lower than the marginal cost, the firm makes losses instead of profits
This solution depends on the assumptions of the model:
- If products are homogeneous, the demand depends only on price. With differentiation and information asymmetries, price can be higher without decreases in demand.
Cournot intro- model assumptions
Developed in 1838 by a French philosopher, mathematician and economist Antoine Augustin Cournot
.
Cournot duopoly assumptions:
Only 2 firms, duopoly
No potential entrants (closed markets)
Homogenous good
Perfect rationality
Perfect information
Only 1 strategic variable: quantity (q)
Production levels are simultaneously decided
The price is determined by the market at a level where the demand equals the joint production of the two firms
The strategic variable is quantity:
The strategic variable is quantity:
Firms choose how much they want to produce, and the price is given by the aggregated market demand (under the hypothesis of standard goods, the DD has a negative slope):
Cournot model - equilibrium
The two firms strategically interact by influencing the (unique) market price through the quantity they set
.
Equilibrium: given the competitor’s choice, firms choose the best strategy to maximize their profits
.
Assume that:
Firms can choose the quantity they prefer in the interval [0,+infinity]
.
Both the profit functions can be differentiated in quantity
Goal: derive the equilibrium (2 steps):
- Determine the set of optimal choices of each firm given the rival’s behavior –> determine reaction functions
. - Intersect the two reaction functions in order to find the combination of mutually compatible decisions (i.e., the Nash-Cournot equilibrium of the game)