8+9. Income Inequality within a country Flashcards

1
Q

Why it is important to pay attention to the distribution of income?

A

One reason to pay attention to the distribution of income is its relationship to POVERTY. For any given average level of income, if income is distributed more unequally, more people will live in poverty. An example makes this point clear. In the year 2005, the average income per capita in India ($2,557) was 21% larger than average income per capita in Pakistan ($2,112). But the fraction of the population living on an income of less than $1.25 per day was 41.6% in India, compared with only 22.5% in Pakistan. The reason for the difference was the distribution of income. Pakistan has a more equal distribution of income than does India, although it has a lower total average income.

Beyond its link to poverty, the distribution of income is also intimately tied to the process of ECONOMIC GROWTH. We will see in this chapter that there are a NUMBER OF CHANNELS THROUGH WHICH INEQUALITY AFFECTS ECONOMIC GROWTH.

Although the empirical evidence is inconclusive, it is possible that a HIGH LEVEL OF INEQUALITY MAY BE GOOD FOR GROWTH AT SOME STAGES OF DEVELOPMENT AND BAD FOR GROWTH AT OTHERS.
Economic growth, in turn, feeds back to affect the degree of income inequality.

Also, REDUCING INEQUALITY IS ONE OF THE MOST IMPORTANT GOALS OF GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC POLICY.

Some POLICIES may achieve the twin goals of REDUCING INCOME INEQUALITY and RAISING ECONOMIC GROWTH. A good example of such a policy is the PUBLIC PROVISION OF EDUCATION.

In OTHER CASES, however, the goals of MAXIMIZING ECONOMIC GROWTH AND REDUCING INCOME INEQUALITY ARE IN CONFLICT.

In this chapter we discuss one such case in detail—the redistribution of income through taxation

To the EXTENT that people derive their HAPPINESSnot from the absolute level of their consumption but from how their RELATIVE CONSUMPTION compares with that of the people around them, income inequality within a country may be more important than differences in income among countries.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
2
Q

Measuring inequality: mean and median

A

In studying income inequality, we will focus on how the residents of a country differ from the country’s average, and thus also how they differ from each other.

Two useful statistics for summarizing a distribution are the mean (the simple average) and the median (the value that has exactly as many observations below it as above).

The mean income is usually higher than the median, because income distributions are skewed. The reason is that income distributions are always skewed—that is, they have a long right tail, rather than being symmetric around their means–> a few households with very high income raise the mean level of income.

At the same time, these households don’t have much effect on median income (because they are rather few).

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
3
Q

Meassuring inequality: Gini Coefficient

A

The Gini coefficient is constructed by measuring the area between the
Lorenz curve and the line of perfect equality and dividing this area by the total area under the line of perfect equality.

The more bowed out is the Lorenz curve, the more unequally
income is distributed…

… the higher will be the value of the Gini coefficient : If a single household receives all household income in the country, it is 1.

If income is distributed perfectly equally, then the value of the Gini coefficient will be 0.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
4
Q

Meassuring inequality: Kuznets hypothesis and Kuznets curve

A

Economist Simon Kuznets hypothesized that AS A COUNTRY DEVELOPED, INEQUALITY WOULD FIRST RISE AND THEN LATER FALL.

Kuznets’s theory implies that if we graphed the LEVEL INEQUALITY (Y-AXES) (E.G. GINNI COEFFE) AS A FUNCTION OF THE LEVEL OF GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT (GDP/CAPITA X-AXES ) THE DATA WOULD TRACE AN INVERTED U-SHAPE CURVE–> KUZNETS CURVE

EVIDENCE OF A KUZNETS CURVE BASED ON THE RETURN TO EDUCATION:

HUMAN CAPITAL: Kuznets reasoned that ECONOMIC GROWTH —represented by the arrival of NEW TECHNOLOGIES AND CHANGES in the structure of the economy—would INITIALLY RAISE THE RATE OF RETURN TO SKILLS, SUCH AS EDUCATION AND ENTREPRENEURIAL BECAUSE SKILLED WORKERS ARE BETTER THAN UNSKILLED WORKERS AT ADAPTING TO NEW MODES OF PRODUCTION.

PHYSICAL CAPITAL: Similarly, NEW TECHNOLOGIES will raise the rate of return to physical capital because technologies are often embodied in new capital goods (new more efficient and productive machines).

WHY DOES INEQUALITY INCREASE AS BOTH HUMAN AND PHYSICAL CAPITAL INCREASE?

Because SKILLED AND CAPITAL ARE FOUND AT THE HIGH END OF THE INCOME DISTRIBUTION (i.e high-income share of the population), THIS INCREASE IN THE RATE OF RETURN TO HUMAN AND PHYSICAL CAPITAL WOULD RAISE INCOME INEQUALITY (i.e. the gap between low-income share of population and high-income share of population widens).

Over time, however, new forces would begin to operate. First, the DISTRIBUTION OF THE QUALITIES THAT DETERMINE INCOME DISTRIBUTION WOULD CHANGE IN A WAY THAT LOWERED INEQUALITY.

The HIGHER RETURN TO SKILLS WOULD INDUCE UNSKILLED WORKERS TO GET AN EDUCATION, and workers would migrate out of regions or sectors that were falling behind and into fast-growing areas.

Second, AS TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS and structural change SLOWED DOWN, THE RATES OF RETURN TO SKILLS WOULD DECLINE, WHICH TENDS TO REDUCE INCOME INEQUALITY.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
5
Q

I. Evidence on Kuznets Curve: examination of the level of inequality in a single country over time: industrialization in England and Wales, 1823-1915

A

One can look for evidence of a Kuznets curve either by examining the level of inequality in a single country over time or by looking at a single point in time in a cross-section of countries with different levels of income.

Figure 13.4 takes the first approach, showing the Gini coefficient in England and Wales from 1823 to 1915. This was a PERIOD OF RAPID INDUSRIALIZATION (TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS/ STRUCTURAL PROCESS/ ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT PROCESS) during which income per capita increased by a factor of roughly three.

The data show a large rise in inequality during the first half of the period and an even larger decline in the second half, so that by 1915, income was distributed more equally than it had been in 1823. Thus, in these historical data, the Kuznets curve is clearly visible

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
6
Q

II. Evidence of a Kuznets Curve: looking at a single point in time in a cross-section of countries with different levels of income.

A

Figure 13.5 (slide 17) takes the cross-sectional approach, graphing income per capita for the year 2009 on the horizontal axis and the Gini coefficient on the vertical axis.

The figure shows many interesting patterns. Many of the most unequal countries are in Latin America. The countries with the lowest levels of inequality are relatively rich countries with well-developed welfare states, such as Sweden and Norway, or else countries with a recent communist past, such as Hungary and Ukraine. The United States stands out as having an unusually high level of inequality for a rich country.

The data in Figure 13.5 do not provide strong evidence of the inverted-U-shaped relationship between development and income inequality that Kuznets hypothesized.

However, using more advanced statistical techniques, a number of researchers believe there is still good evidence for the Kuznets curve. The problem, they argue, is that many OTHER FACTORS, IN ADDITION TO THE LEVEL OF DEVELOPMENT, AFFECT A COUNTRY’S LEVEL OF INEQUALITY. Once the analysis accounts for these factors, the Kuznets curve “comes out of hiding.

According to a study by the economist Robert Barro, the peak of the Kuznets curve comes at a per-capita income level of $4,815 (in 2000 dollars), corresponding roughly to the income level of Romania in the figure. Barro’s estimates imply that a quadrupling of income per capita from the value that is at the peak of the Kuznets curve (as would happen if Romania grew to have the level of income per capita of the United Kingdom) would lead to a reduction of 0.05 in the Gini coefficient.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
7
Q

How does growth affect the incomes of the poor?
(Hint: KUZNETS CURVE + Relationship between the average income per capita for bottom quintile (20% of the poorest population) and the average income per capita of a country)

A

The reason economists care about income inequality is that it is related to poverty.

If there is a KUZNETS CURVE, it is theoretically possible that economic growth can be bad for the poorest people in a country. Economic growth can be bad for the poorest people in a country. Specifically, GROWTH’S EFFECT OF RAISING THE AVERAGE LEVEL OF INCOME MAY BE COUNTERACTED BY WIDENING OF INEQUALITY AS THE POOREST PEOPLE FALL FARTHER BELOW THE AVERAGE.

Although the influence of inequality on the income of the poor is apparent in Figure 13.6 (comparison of the average income per capita (x-axis) and the average income per capita for the bottom quintile (y-axis)), the overall impression that the figure gives is that THE MOST IMPORTANT DETERMINANT OF THE INCOMES OF THE POOR IS A COUNTRY’S AVERAGE LEVEL OF GDP. –> POOR PEOPLE IN A RICH, UNEQUAL COUNTRY ARE FAR BETTER OFF THAN POOR PEOPLE IN A POOR EGALITARIANN COUNTRY.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
8
Q

How do growth-promoting policies affect income inequality?

A

Using these data, Dollar and Kraay examined WHETHER SPECIFIC POLICIES HAD DIFFERENT EFFECTS ON THE INCOME OF THE POOR VERSUS OVERALL INCOME.

Their key finding was that POLICIES THAT AFFECT GROWTH policies that affect growth for good or ill generally DON’T SIGNIFICANTLY AFFECT THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME.

For example, RULE OF LAW AND OPENNESS TO TRADE RAISE OVERALL INCOME IN A COUNTRY AND HAVE POSITIVE BUT MINOR EFFECTS ON THE SHARE OF INCOME GOINGTO THE LOWEST QUINTILE.
Similarly, a high rate of inflation and a high level of government consumption is bad for overall income and reduce (but only slightly) the share of income going to the poor.

Another approach to the question of HOW GROWTH AFFECTS THE INCOMES OF THE POOR is to look at INDIVIDUAL EPISODES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH.

A recent study examined 88 episodes in which the average level of income per capita in a country grew over a decade. In each case, the authors looked at data on the distribution of income at the beginning and ending points of the episode. They found that in 77 cases, the income of the poorest fifth of the population also grew. In all but one of the other cases, either growth of average income was very low, or the decline in the income of the poor was temporary and was reversed in subsequent decades. In only one case (Colombia between 1970 and 1980) was there rapid growth of average income.

Summarizing the results of these studies, GROWTH IS ALMOST GOOD FOR THE POOR, AND SO ARE THE POLICIES THAT LEAD TO GROWTH.
Nevertheless, THESE POLICIES DON’T SIGNIFICANTLY AFFECT THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
9
Q

Source of income inequality:

Why is there income inequality at all? What are the three main sources of inequality?

A

The reason income inequality exists is that PEOPLE IN AN ECONOMY DIFFER FROM EACH OTHER IN MANY WAYS THAT ARE RELEVANT TO THERI INCOMES.

DIFFERENCES IN HUMAN CAPITAL OWNERSHIP OF PHYSICAL CAPITAL, GEOGRAPHY:
Differences occur in human capital (both education and health), in where people live (city versus countryside or different geographical regions of a country), in their ownership of physical capital, in the particular skills they have, and even in their luck. These differences are translated into differences in income by the economic environment.

So, 3 MAIN SOURCES OF INEQUALITY:

1) HUMAN CAPITAL: education and skills; health
2) GEOGRAPHY: urban or rural context
3) OWNERSHIP OF PHYSICAL CAPITAL

A man may be rich because he has a skill that is in high demand, because his parents gave him money when he was born, or because he just happened to be in the right place when a good job became available. He might be poor because he lives in a part of the country that is economically depressed because he suffers from a physical ailment that limits his earnings, or because he had no access to education.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
10
Q

Determination of income inequality: Education

A

Suppose that the only characteristic that determines income is the NUMBER OF YEARS OF EDUCATION.
To get from this distribution of education (fraction of the population in each of the possible educational categories) to a distribution of income, we need to know how education translates into income.

A useful concept, introduced in Chapter 6, is that of the RETURN TO EDUCATION: THE PERCENTAGE RISE IN EARNING THAT RESULTS FROM AN ADDITIONAL YEAR OF EDUCATION. It shows the RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN YEARS OF EDUCATION AND INCOME.

For the purposes of our example, we use a return to education of 10% per year. Thus, if a worker with no education earns an income of 100, a worker with one year of education will earn 110, a worker with two years of education will earn 121, and so on.

Putting together data on the distribution of education and the return to education, we can derive the distribution of income—that is, the fraction of the population that earns each level of income.

Using this analysis, we can examine what determines differences in the distribution of income among countries and what causes the distribution of income to change over time within a given country.

FROM THE POINT OF VIEW OF EDUCATION: DIFFERENCES AMONG COUNTRIES OR CHANGES OVER TIME MUST HAVE THEIR SOURCE IN EITHER THE RETURN TO EDUCATION OR IN EDUCATION DISTRIBUTION.

Let’s assume, there is a change in the return to education. We compare two countries with the identical distribution of education, but different returns to education: the first country has the return to education of 10%, whereas the other one - 5%. Changing the return to education from 10% to 5% lowers the Gini coefficient from 0.068 to 0.035.

We conduct a similar analysis of the effect of changing the distribution of education. In this case, the two countries have the same return to education, but differ in their distributions of education: first country has a narrower distribution of education—that is, more people in the middle educational groups and fewer people in the lowest and highest educational groups. this narrower distribution of education translates into a narrower distribution of income as well—its Gini coefficient of 0.049 is much smaller than that of the broader distribution of education and thus of income.

Nevertheless, we changed only one determinant of inequality at a time. More realistically, however, we would expect that BOTH MIGHT CHANGE SIMULTANEOUSLY, EITHER REINFORCING EACH OTHER OR WORKING IN OPPOSITE DIRECTIONS.

For example, in a given country, the distribution of education might become more equal while the return to education rises. In such a case, the total effect on inequality would depend on WHICH FORCE IS STRONGER.

Further, once we move beyond this simple model, we must remember that many characteristics affect income.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
11
Q

Reasons for the rise in income inequality?

A

1) TECHNOLOGICAL ADVANCES : skill-biased technological change:

Information technology COMPLEMENTED SKILLS OD EDUCATED WORKERS, INCREASINF THEIR PRODUCTIVITY AND RATE OF RETURN, WHILE DOING LESS TO RAISE THE PRODUCTIY OF LESS EDUCATED WORKERS.

The new technology also INCREASED RETURNS TO FLEXIBILITY (to work with a
new technology) or entrepreneurial spirit. If valid, EXPECRT that at some point the INEQUALITY-INDUCING EFFECTS OF THE CURRENT TECHNOLOGICAL REVOLUTION DISSIPATE.

2) INCREASES IN INTRNATIONAL TRASDE: STOLPER-SAMUELSON: the returns to the aundant factor of production will increase, while the returns to the scarce factor of production will decline. The effect of trade on inequality depens on HOW THE SKILLS, OF THOSE WHOSE RETURNS ARE AFFECTED ARE DISTRIBUTED IN THE POPULATION.

3) SUPERSTAR DYNAMICS: : represents a RISE IN THE RETURN TO CERTAIN QUALITIES and thus increases income inequality.
People with the highest levels of some qualities earn much more than people with only slightly lower qualifications (e.g. sports)

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
12
Q

I. Effect of income inequality on economic growth: Examination of channels through which inequality affect economic growth: Accumulation of physical capital

A

1) EFFCT OF THE ACCUMULATION OF PHYSICAL CAPITALl:
One channel through which income inequality can have a beneficial effect on economic growth is SAVING RATES. A country with a HIGHER SAVING RATE will have a HIGHER STEADY-STATE LEVEL OF INCOME/CAPITA, and a country that raises its saving rate will experience a period of TRANSITIONAL GROWTH AS IT MOVES TOWARD A NEW STEADY STATE.

–>INEQUALITY AND SAVING RATE:
_________________________
Inequality is related to the saving rate for the simple reason that SAVING RATES TEND TO RISE WITH INCOME. That is, the HIGHER a person’s INCOME is, the HIGHER his or her SAVING RATE is likely to be. The total amount of saving in a country is the sum of saving by people in all different income groups. The MORE INEQUAL IS INCOME—that is, the HIGHER THE FRACTION OF TOTAL INCOME EARNED BY RICH PEOPLE - HIGHER WILL BE TOTAL SAVING.

The saving rate for the highest quintile is almost three times the saving rate for the lowest quintile.

For example, suppose that we took one dollar of income away from a household in the richest quintile and gave it to a household in the poorest quintile. Such a redistribution of income would reduce the degree of inequality in the country. But because the average saving of the poor out of their income (9.0 cents per dollar) is smaller than the average saving of the rich out of their income (24.4 cents per dollar), the effect of redistributing income would be to reduce total savings by 15.4 cents (that is, 24.4–9.0) for every dollar transferred.

INCOME INEQUALITY AS AN ESSENTIAL PREREQUISITE FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH (KEYNES):
John Maynard Keynes, writing of the late 19th and early 20th centuries, argued that income inequality, which put money in the hands of those LEASR LIKELY TO SPEND IT ON CONSUMPTION, was an essential, though distasteful, prerequisite for economic growth: It was precisely the INEQULITY OF THE DISTRIBUTON OF WEALTH WHICH MADE POSSIBLE THOSE VAST ACCUMULATIONS OF FIXED WEALTH AND OF CAPITAL improvements which distinguished that age from all others. The IMMENSE ACCUMULATIONS OF FIXED CAPITAL which, to the great benefit of mankind, were built up during the half-century before the war, COULD NEVER HAVE COME ABOUT IN A SOCIETY WHERE WEALTH WAS DIVIDED EQUITABLY.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
13
Q

II. Effect of inequality on economic growth through the accumulation of human capital

A

Although a MORE UNEQUAL DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME IS BENEFICAL FOR ACCUMULATING PHYSICAL CAPITAL AND THUS FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH–>

OPPOSITE SITUATION IN THE CASE OF HUMAN CAPITAL:
______________________
A MORE UNEQUAL DISTIRBUTION OF INCOME LEADS TO LOWER HUMAN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION. The source of the difference between these two cases goes back to one of the fundamental differences in the two factors of production. HUMAN CAPITAL IS “INSTALLED” IN A SPECIFIC PERSON, IT WORKS ONLY WHEN ITS OWNER WORKS, AND IT CANNOT BE TRASNDERRED FROM ONE PERSON TO ANOTHER

By contrast, a piece of physical capital can be used by different people at different times and can easily be sold by one person to another. As a result, it is fairly easy for one person to own physical capital that is used in production by a different person. For example, a rich woman may own a factory that uses the labor of hundreds of other people. But it is almost impossible for a person to own the human capital that is installed in someone else.

Thus, unlike the case for physical capital, the opportunities that any one person has to invest in human capital are limited to the human capital that he can install in himself.

The effect of inequality in the presence of this limitation on human capital investment can be easily seen in a simple example. Consider two people, one rich and one poor. Each person has two types of investment that can be made: in human capital or in physical capital. We assume that at low levels of investment, the MARGINAL PRODUCT OF HUMAN CAPITAL IS VERY HIGH. But as the quantity of human capital that is invested in any one person increases, its marginal product goes down (since there is a limitation–> so to say Sättigungspunkt).

By contrast, the MARGINAL PRODUCT OF PHYSICAL CAPITAL that any one investor faces does not depend on the amount that person invests in physical capital because any single person’s investment is minuscule in relation to the national level of capital.

The relationship between the quantities that an individual invests in human and physical capital and the marginal products earned by these investments is shown in Figure 13.1 (slide 33). As Figure 13.11 makes clear, if a person has only a little money, he or she will invest in human capital rather than in physical capital because it is always better to invest in the form of capital with the highest marginal product.

But people with a lot of money to invest will invest their marginal dollars in physical capital. More specifically, if a person has less than I* available to invest, he or she will invest it all in human capital (higher marginal product for this level of I). If he or she has more than I to invest, then he or she will invest I* in human capital and the rest of his or her money in physical capital.

One of the implications of this story is that human capital will be distributed much more equally (max. investments in human capital up to the level of I, no investments in physical capital at all, since income of poor people is limited to the level I (assumption)) than physical capital (investments are made for an infinite large level income).

The reason is that many poorer people will do all of their investment in the form of human capital and therefore will own no physical capital, whereas many wealthy people will hold almost all of their wealth in the form of physical capital. Recall the definition of Gini-coefficient (1- complete inequality; 0-perfect equality). Gini coefficients can also be used to measure the degree of inequality in the ownership of specific assets such as physical capital and human capital. In the United States, the Gini coefficient is 0.78 for physical capital and 0.14 for years of education (considered as a human capital). Thus, ownership of physical capital is indeed more unequal than that of human capital.

Once again, why is human capital more equally distributed than physical capital:
Both people with income up to I* and people with the income I< will invest in human capital up to I, since the marginal product of investment into human capital up to this level is higher than that of physical capital. On the other hand, investment in the physical capital will only be done by people whose income lies above the level I*. Only a few rich people possess incomes of this magnitude and thus the ownership of physical capital will be accumulated by a smaller share of population as compared to human capital accumulation.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
14
Q

II. Effect of inequality on economic growth through accumulation of human capital: How does inequality affect the accumulation of human capital?

A

Let’s consider two people, one with more than I* available to invest, and the other with less than I. The person with less than I will invest all of the wealth in human capital; the person with more than I* will invest I* in human capital and the rest of the wealth in physical capital. Notice that the marginal product of the last dollar invested by the poor person is higher than the marginal product of the last dollar invested by the rich person.

If INCOME REDISTRIBUTED FROM RICH TO THE POOR PERSON, two things will happen.
1) HUMAN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION WILL RISE because the poor person will invest extra money in human capital, whereas the rich person will reduce investment in physical capital.

2) TOTAL OUTPUT WILL GO UP because the MARGINAL PRODUCT OF HUMAN CAPITAL BEING INVESTED IN BY THE POOR PERSON IS HIGHERr than the marginal product of physical capital that the rich person invests in.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
15
Q

What kind of effects does inequality have on the pace of economic growth at different stages of growth?

A

The different effects of inequality on physical and human capital accumulation - beneficial in the case of physical capital and harmful in the case of human capital—suggest that inequality may have different effects on the pace of economic growth at different stages of growth.

As Keynes’s quotation suggests, the driving force of 19th-century economic growth was the accumulation of physical capital.

For example, many of the new technologies of this period were oriented toward the more effective use of physical capital—that is, building better machines. Thus, in this period, inequality may have contributed to economic growth.

However, as discussed in Chapter 6, economic growth in the last several decades, at least among the most developed countries, has been driven by the accumulation of human capital rather than physical capital. In this circumstance, inequality is detrimental to growth.

How well did you know this?
1
Not at all
2
3
4
5
Perfectly
16
Q

How does the openness to international capital flows influence the way inequality affects factor accumulation in developing countries?

A

For developing countries, openness to international capital flows also will influence how inequality affects factor accumulation.

!!! If a country is open to flows of physical capital, then the beneficial effects of inequality on the saving rate will no longer be relevant because investment does not have to be financed out of domestic savings (i.e. accumulation of wealth by a few rich people and thus higher savings doesn’t matter anymore for a higher income level in a country, since investment in an open world doesn’t have to be only financed from domestic savings).

On the other hand, the negative effects of inequality on human capital investment will remain.

Thus, the level of inequality that maximizes factor accumulation will be lower in a country open to capital flows than in one that is closed to capital flows.

Why? Due to openness to international capital flows, inequality in terms of physical capital accumulation among the population will decline, since high investments in capital through high domestic savings of rich people can also be financed from foreign savings
–> No incentive to increase inequality -> higher domestic savings isn’t the only way to finance capital investments.

17
Q

What plays the most important role in explaining income differences among countries? Base your answer on the idea of how income inequality affect factor accumulation in the economy (physical and human capital)

A

The preceding two channels through which income inequality may affect growth involve mechanisms by which a country’s level of income inequality can affect the accumulation of factors of production, specifically physical and human capital.

As we have seen in previous chapters, DIFFERENCES IN THE ACCUMULATION OF FACTORS OF PRODUCTION ARE NOT THE ONLY SOURCE OF DIFFERENCE IN INCOME AMONG COUNTRIES.

Rather, DIFFERENCES IN THE PRODUCTIVITY WITH WHICH THESE FACTORS ARE USED play an equally important role in explaining income differences among countries.

18
Q

III. Effect of inequality on economic growth: effect of inequality of productivity
1) income redistribution

A

In this part, we examine how INCOME INEQUALITY CAN REDUCE THE EFFICIENCY OF AN ECONOMY.
The first way in which inequality can affect the efficiency of production is THROUGH THE CHANNEL OF INCOME REDISTRIBUTION, the process by which governments take MONEY AWAY FROM THOS WITH HIGH INCOME AND GIVE IT TO THOSE WITH LOW INCOME.

When incomes are unequal, governments face pressure to redistribute income. Governments accomplish this goal through TAXATION. But as we have already seen, TAXES LEAD TO INEFFICIENCY. So by raising the likelihood that the government will want to use taxes to redistribute income, inequality can indirectly LOWER THE LEVEL OF EFFICIENCY (higher prices?), and THUS OUTPUT (SUPPLY SIDE PRODUCES LESS DUE TO TAXES).

To examine this relationship between inequality and efficiency in detail, we consider a simple MODEL OF THE PROCESS OF INCOME REDISTRIBUTION. To keep our model tractable, we assume that the income redistribution is the only thing the government does—that is, we ignore other government functions such as the provision of public goods. We assume that redistribution takes the following form.

1) the government taxes all workers at the same rate. That is, all workers pay the SAME FRACTION OF THEIR INCOME AS TAXESs, so WORKERS WITH HIGH INCOMES PAY MORE TAXES THAN THOSE WITH LOW INCOME.
2) the government takes the REVENUE COLLECTED FTOM THIS TAX AND PAYS IT BACK TO WORKTER IN EQUAL AMOUNT–> LUMP-TRANSFER.

Taxes and transfers are important because they affect workers’ incomes.

A worker’s PRETAX INCOME is the income that he or she earns before any taxes are collected.

A worker’s DISPOSABLE INCOME is his or her PRETAX INCOME - TAXES PAID PLUS THE TRANSFER that he or she receives from the government. The difference between a worker’s pretax income and disposable income will depend on where in the income distribution he or she falls.

Because we are assuming that the government uses all of its revenues to make lump-sum transfers, the size of the lump-sum transfer each worker receives will equal the mean amount of taxes collected per worker, which in turn will equal the tax rate times the mean of pretax income.

Thus, a worker who had pretax income exactly equal to the mean pretax income would receive a lump-sum transfer exactly equal to what was paid in taxes. A worker who had pretax income below the mean would receive a lump-sum transfer larger than what he or she paid in taxes, and a worker who had pretax income above the mean would receive a transfer smaller than what he or she paid in taxes.

Because taxes serve to redistribute income from high-income to low-income workers, the distribution of disposable income (pre-tax income - taxes + lump-sum transfer) will be more equal than the distribution of pretax income (income a person earns before any taxes are collected).

Further, we can use the tax rate (i.e., the fraction of pretax income collected by the government) as a measure of the degree of redistribution.

If the government collects only a small percentage of pretax income and redistributes it, then disposable income will be almost as unequally distributed as pretax income.

If the government collects a large fraction of pretax income and redistributes it, then disposable income will be distributed much more equally than pretax income.

19
Q

III. How does inequality affect a country’s productivity?

–> Relationship between taxes and productivity: income redistribution through taxes
TAX RATE AS A MESURE OF THE DEGREE OF REDISTRIBUTION

A

The first way in which INEQUALITY CAN AFFECT THE EFFICIENCY OF PRODUCTION IS THROUGH THE CHANNEL OF INCOME REDISTRIBUTION.

Now let’s consider the relationship between TAXES and PRODUCTIVITY.

When taxes are high, taxpayers have an incentive to avoid paying them, either legally or illegally. But avoidance entails nonproductive activities, ranging from a firm’s keeping two sets of books (an illegal means of evading taxes) to a person’s staying home rather than working (a legal means of tax avoidance).

As a result, TAXES WILL LOWER EFFICIENCY AND SO WILL LOWER PRETAX INCOME FOR ALL WORKERS.

Tthe effect of taxes on productivity grows larger as the tax rate rises. When taxes are low, the decrease in efficiency that results from an increase in taxes is relatively small; WHEN TAXES ARE HIGH, THE MARGINAL LOSS OF EFFICIENCY FROM A FURTHER INCREASE IN TAXES IS LARGER.

We can now examine HOW MUCH INCOME REDISTRIBUTION DIFFERENT WORKERS WOULD PREFER:

!!! LUMP-TRANSFER: the government takes the revenue that it collects from this tax and pays it back to workers in equal amounts : lump-sum transfer.

!!! SIZE OF THE LUMP-SUM TRANSFER= MEAN AMOUNT OF TAXES COLLECTED PER WORKER : –> tax rate * mean pretax income.

Consider first a worker with PRETAX INCOME ABOVE THE MEAN LEVEL in the country. This worker will be made WORSE OFF BY REDISTRIBUTION:

1) He or she will receive less back in the form of a lump-sum transfer than he or she paid in taxes.
2) The reduction in economic efficiency resulting from redistributive taxation will also lower the worker’s pretax income. Thus, a worker with pretax income above the mean will favor a tax rate of zero.

In the case of a worker with pretax income exactly equal to the mean, only one of the two effects previously described is operative.

This worker receives a lump-sum transfer exactly equal to his or her tax payment, so in this sense he or she is not hurt by redistribution. But the negative effect of redistributive taxes on efficiency, and thus on pretax income, nonetheless makes him or her worse off. Therefore, this worker also will be against redistribution.

For a worker who earns less than the mean pretax income, the two effects of a tax ( benefits from lump-sum transfer and loss in efficiency) work in opposite directions. The lump-sum payment he or she will receive from the government will be larger than taxes, so his or her disposable income rises. However, the inefficiency resulting from high taxes lowers his or her pretax income, making him or her worse off. Thus, a worker with income below the mean faces a trade-off between the benefits that he or she gets from redistribution and the costs of inefficiency as a result of taxation.

The level of taxation (and thus redistribution) that maximizes such a worker’s disposable income will depend on how far below the mean his or her level of pretax income is.

The farther below the mean the pretax income, the more important to him or her is redistribution, the less harmful is reduced pretax income, and the higher the level of taxation he or she will prefer.

A worker who had zero pretax income—that is, one whose disposable income consisted solely of the lump-sum transfer he or she received—would prefer a tax rate that maximized total government revenue and thus the size of the per-person transfer.

!!! THERE IS ALWAYS A NEGATIVE EFFECT OF TAXES ON EFFICIENC!!!

20
Q

IV. Effect of inequality on economic growth: Sociopolitical unrest in response to income inequality. Several ways of expressing pressure for redistribution

A

The model of redistribution through taxation just presented a simplistic view of the political process: MORE INEQUALITY RESULTS IN MORE DEMAND FOR REDISTRIBUTION, so more redistribution takes place.

A more realistic view of the political process would acknowledge that decisions are not necessarily made by simple majority voting, either in formal democracies (where, despite the rule of “one person), one or in non-democratic countries.

Given this observation, we might revise our conclusion to say that countries with a more unequal distribution of income might have more pressure for redistribution but not necessarily more actual redistribution.

The PRESSURE FOR REDISTRIBUTION is expressed in several ways, all of them SLOWING GROWTH

One expression is through political instability because different groups compete for power. Unstable political situations discourage investment, as occurs when, for example, people who build factories worry that their property might be confiscated following some potential future revolution or other change in government.

A second expression of the pressure for redistribution is crime. Property crime is often the attempt by poor people to redistribute resources through channels other than the political system. Other forms of social unrest that can be motivated by severe inequality, such as rioting, also lead to the destruction of property, even if they do not result in a redistribution of income. Crime not only wastes the time and the energy of criminals themselves, it also wastes the resources of those who have to spend money preventing it.

In The Wealth of Nations (1776), Adam Smith wrote of societies with a high degree of inequality that “civil government, so far as it is instituted for the security of property, is in reality, instituted for the defence of the rich against the poor, or of those who have some property against those who have none at all.” By this logic, greater inequality requires a larger government—and, thus, reduced economic efficiency*—simply to secure the property rights of the rich.

Economic efficiency* is when all goods and factors of production in an economy are distributed or allocated to their most valuable uses and waste is eliminated or minimized. Economic efficiency can involve efficient production decisions within firms and industries, efficient consumption decisions by individual consumers, and efficient distribution of consumer and producer goods across individual consumers and firm.

21
Q

How an increase in income inequality affects the desired tax rate?

A

Finally, we can analyze the EFFECT OF INCOME DISTRIBUTION ON THE LEVEL OF TAXES, AND THUS THE EFFECT ON EFFICIENCY.

Consider what happens when the distribution of pretax income changes, holding CONSTANT THE MEAN OF INCOME.

Suppose, for example, that INCOME BECOMES MORE UNEQUAL.

The wider the distribution of income is, the farther will the median level of pretax income be below the mean.

Put another way: If two countries have the same average pretax income, then the median level of pretax income will be lower in the country with a more unequal distribution of income. As Figure 23 (slide 40) shows, when median pretax income falls, the rate of taxation favored by the median voter rises.

Higher inequality leads to more redistribution and more taxation—and, for the reasons discussed in Chapter 12, a lower level of efficiency. Through this channel, inequality lowers the average level of income–> less output produced?

22
Q

How are actual rates of taxation determined? Relationship between income inequality and the desired tax rate.

A

Figure 13.12 (slide 39) illustrates the relationship between a worker’s desired tax rate and his or her level of pretax income.

All workers with pretax income greater than or equal to the mean will want a tax rate of zero. Workers with pretax income below the mean will want a positive tax rate. This desired tax rate will be higher for workers with lower pretax income. Workers whose disposable income solely consists of the lump-sum transfer only would prefer a tax rate that maximizes revenue of government (revenue-maximizing tax rate).

Using our analysis of desired rates of taxation (and thus redistribution), we can address the question of how actual rates of taxation are determined. The answer is that the determination of tax rates is a political process. To analyze this process, we can think about a simplified version of politics. Suppose that each person has one vote and that the only issue over which there is voting is whether to raise or lower the tax rate.

In this situation, the TAX RATE is easy to calculate: It will be the RATE THAT IS OPTIMAL FOR THE VOTER WITH THE MEDIAN LEVEL OF PRETAX INCOME.

The logic is simple. We have already established that people with higher pretax incomes will favor lower tax rates and that everyone at or above the mean level of pretax income will favor a tax rate of zero.

If the tax rate is higher than the level favored by the voter with median pretax income, then he or she would be in favor of lowering the tax rate, as would everyone with pretax income higher than his or hers.

By definition, half the population has pretax income above the median level. If all these people, as well as the person with median income, favor lowering the tax rate, then a majority will support lowering taxes. Similarly, if the tax rate is lower than the level favored by the person with median pretax income, then a majority will favor raising the tax rate.

Thus, the tax rate chosen will be the one preferred by the person with the median level of pretax income, who is often referred to as the median voter.

Figure 13.12 (slide 40) shows the median level of pretax income and the tax rate favored by the worker with that level of pretax income.

Notice that the median level of pretax income is below the mean level of pretax income, in accordance with the fact mentioned in Section 13.1 that median income is always (at least in all of the countries for which we have data) below the mean.

Thus, the tax rate selected by the median voter will be above zero!

23
Q

Tutorial 8: Many companies are working to perfect “distance learning” technology, by which a single professor can teach students at dozens or even hundreds of colleges and universities. Using the framework of the lecture, explain how
such a technological change would affect the distribution of income among professors.

A

The perfection of “distance learning” serves to create a superstar effect for professors, thereby raising the level of inequality among professors. Because a single professor will be able to teach many students at any given time, only a few qualified professors will be needed, and those professors will earn a high wage.

24
Q

Tutorial 8: How would the availability of student loans to finance education influence the relationship between inequality and the accumulation of factors of production? In particular, how would student loans affect the level of inequality that maximizes factor accumulation?

A
25
Q

Beyond income distribution: Economic mobility: CHANGE OF THE POSITION IN THE INCOME DISTRIBUTION

A

A second key aspect of inequality is economic mobility: the movement of people from one part of the income distribution to another.

To see the importance of economic mobility, let us consider two countries that have the same distributions of income but different levels of mobility.

In one country, people are constantly SHIFTING FROM ONE PART OF THE INCOME DISTRIBUTION TO ANOTHER, whereas in the second country, people always remain at the same position in the income distribution.

Clearly, the first country—with higher mobility—has greater equality in an important sense, even though an economist looking only at the Gini coefficients in the two countries would not observe this.

Economic mobility can be measured on many different time horizons. For example, we might be interested in year-to-year or decade-to-decade MOVEMENTS OF INDIVIDUALS THROUGH INCOME DISTRIBUTION.

Economists frequently examine INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY (i.e., the change in the economic status of families from one generation to the next). Intergenerational mobility is often described as “equality of opportunity.”

A high degree of intergenerational mobility means that the children of poor parents have the same prospects—that is, the same probability of being rich or poor—as do the children of wealthy parents. Where intergenerational mobility is low, children are likely to be in the same part of the income distribution as their parents.

One way to study mobility (especially intergenerational mobility) is to look at a transition matrix, a table showing the probabilities that individuals will move from one income group to another. Table 13.3 (slide 44) is an example of a transition matrix using data on families in the United States. The rows of the matrix consider different income groups of the parents. The top row represents the parents in the lowest quintile of the income distribution, the second row represents parents in the second quintile, and so on. Within each row, the columns are the probability that children of these families were found in specific quintiles when they were adults. For example, there is 6% probability that a person whose parents were in the lowest income quintile will be in the highest income quintile.

Measuring mobility is much more difficult than measuring inequality, because it requires being able to track families over a long period of time.

For that reason, we know much less about how mobility compares among countries than we do about comparisons of inequality. One study that put together consistent estimates for nine countries found the lowest mobility in the United States and United Kingdom, mid-range mobility in France, Germany, and Sweden, and the highest mobility in Canada, Finland, Norway, and Denmark.

.