5.4 Expenditure Reducing Policies to Rectify a Current Account Deficit Flashcards
1. What are examples of expenditure reducing policies to rectify a current account deficit?
Examples of expenditure reducing policies include contractionary fiscal policies such as an increase in income tax, an increase in corporation tax, and a cut in government spending. They also include contractionary monetary policies such as a rise in interest rates or a decrease in the money supply. These policies aim to reduce aggregate demand (AD) in the economy, which in turn reduces incomes and the marginal propensity to import. This leads to a reduction in imports and an improvement in the trade balance in the current account, rectifying a current account deficit.
evaluation: What are the potential drawbacks of implementing expenditure reducing policies to rectify a current account deficit?
Expenditure reducing policies conflict with other macroeconomic objectives of the government. While these policies may improve the trade balance, they often have adverse side effects. One such effect is a fall in economic growth, potentially leading to a recession. Additionally, expenditure reducing policies can result in a rise in unemployment. These negative consequences are often considered more significant than the benefits of an improved trade position, leading to the infrequent use of these policies to reduce current account deficits
Q: What is protectionism?
A: Protectionism refers to policies implemented by a country to restrict or limit international trade. It includes measures such as imposing or increasing tariffs, quotas, embargoes, domestic subsidies, and non-tariff barriers like red tape and standards. These policies aim to increase the price of imported goods or block imports, thereby reducing expenditure on imports and potentially improving the trade balance in the current account to rectify a current account deficit.
evaluation: Q: What is one potential drawback of using protectionism to address a trade deficit?
A: One potential drawback of using protectionism to address a trade deficit is the likelihood of strong retaliation by trading partners. Trading partners may react negatively to the imposition of protectionist measures, as it affects their economy and exporters. This can lead to a tit-for-tat situation, where retaliation is enacted back on the initial country’s imports, resulting in a significant reduction in export revenue and potentially worsening their trade deficit over time. Protectionism can result in a zero-sum game for all involved.
evaluation: Q: How can protectionism affect consumers?
A: Protectionism, such as tariffs, can increase prices for consumers and create a deadweight welfare loss of consumer surplus. Tariffs act as taxes on imports, thereby raising the price of imported goods. This particularly affects key imports like clothing, food, vehicles, and manufactured goods, which are often relied upon by low-income individuals who spend a greater proportion of their income on these goods. As a result, protectionism can be regressive and negatively impact consumer welfare.
evaluation: Q: How does protectionism conflict with the principles of the World Trade Organization (WTO)?
A: Protectionism contradicts the aims and principles of the World Trade Organization (WTO), to which many countries are signatories. The WTO requires member countries to only impose protectionist measures that are fair and consistent, as approved by the organization. Breaking these rules by using tariffs to reduce current account deficits can result in heavy fines imposed by the WTO or allow trading partner countries to legally retaliate with stricter measures.
evaluation: Q: How can protectionist measures lead to inflation and conflict with government macroeconomic objectives?
A: Protectionist measures, such as tariffs and quotas, can be inflationary and create a conflict with government macroeconomic objectives. Tariffs increase the price of imported goods, including raw materials and commodities, thereby increasing production costs for businesses reliant on these imports. These higher costs are passed on to consumers through higher prices, causing cost-push inflation. Even finished goods imported at higher prices can contribute to inflationary pressures throughout the economy.
Q: How does protectionism affect the allocation of resources on a global scale?
A: Protectionism worsens the world allocation of resources. By promoting domestic production without considering comparative advantage, protectionism directs resources toward less efficient domestic producers rather than more efficient foreign producers. This distortion leads to a misallocation of resources, resulting in allocative inefficiency. Comparative advantage is compromised, and global resources are not optimally utilized.
Q: How can the exchange rate be weakened to address a current account deficit?
A: The exchange rate can be weakened through various measures, such as reducing interest rates to increase hot money outflows, increasing the money supply, or selling domestic currency reserves. A weak exchange rate makes exports cheaper and imports more expensive. Economic theory suggests that this would lead to a decrease in the demand for imports and expenditure on imports, while increasing the demand for exports and revenue generated by exports. Both effects work towards improving the trade balance of the current account, reducing a current account deficit, or potentially moving it into a surplus.
evaluation: Q: What condition must be satisfied for the exchange rate weakening strategy to be effective?
A: The effectiveness of the exchange rate weakening strategy depends on whether the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied. The condition states that the sum of the price elasticities of demand for exports (PEDx) and imports (PEM) must be greater than 1 (PEDx + PEM > 1). When export prices fall, demand for exports tends to rise, resulting in increased export revenue in domestic currency terms regardless of the price elasticity. However, if the demand for imports is price inelastic, as import prices rise, the expenditure on imports may increase, although to a lesser extent than the price rise. To offset the increase in import expenditure, greater export revenue is required, which can be achieved when the sum of the price elasticities of demand for exports and imports is greater than 1. If the Marshall-Lerner condition is not satisfied, there will be a net increase in import expenditure relative to export revenue, worsening the trade balance and current account deficit contrary to what economic theory suggests.
evaluation: Q: Why may the Marshall-Lerner condition not be achieved in the short run?
A: The Marshall-Lerner condition is unlikely to be achieved in the short run due to the price inelasticity of demand for both imports and exports. Contracts and agreements make it difficult for countries to immediately switch their international buying and selling patterns. Consumers and businesses often take time to adjust and find substitutes in response to changes in exchange rates. As a result, a phenomenon known as the J-curve effect occurs, where the current account position for a country is more likely to deteriorate from an initial deficit to a worse deficit before eventually improving and recording a surplus after a noticeable time lag. This time lag allows for the adjustment of contracts and the search for substitutes in response to a permanently lower exchange rate. The achievement of the Marshall-Lerner condition, where the price elasticities of demand for both exports and imports sum to greater than 1, requires time and adjustments in economic agents’ behavior.
evaluation: Q: How can the weakening of the exchange rate lead to inflation and conflict with macroeconomic objectives?
A: Weakening the exchange rate can lead to inflation, specifically demand-pull inflation. As aggregate demand (AD) increases in the economy, it puts pressure on existing factors of production, leading to an increase in their prices. Additionally, cost-push inflation can occur as firms must now pay more for imported raw materials, which have become more expensive due to the weakened exchange rate. Consequently, the costs of production for firms rise, and they pass on these extra costs through higher prices, causing cost-push inflation. Inflationary pressures can conflict with macroeconomic objectives, particularly if a nation heavily depends on imported commodities and raw materials. This situation can dampen economic growth and even lead to stagflation, characterized by high inflation and low economic growth.
evaluation: Q: What potential issue can arise from purposefully weakening the exchange rate to improve the current account?
A: Purposefully weakening the exchange rate to improve the current account can lead to retaliation and currency wars. When countries manage and weaken their exchange rates to gain an advantage in their current account deficits, it can be seen as a protectionist action that causes outrage in trading partner countries. The increased cost of their exports due to a weaker currency reduces their export revenue and economic growth. In response, trading partner countries may weaken their own exchange rates, leading to a situation where no country has a cheaper export advantage, resulting in a zero-sum game. Currency wars and retaliatory actions can escalate tensions and disrupt international trade relationships.
evaluation: Q: How does the severity of trade restrictions imposed by foreign governments impact the effectiveness of a weak exchange rate strategy?
A: The effectiveness of a weak exchange rate strategy depends on the severity of trade restrictions imposed by foreign governments. If foreign governments have strict controls that limit the quantity of domestic exports entering their country, a fall in the exchange rate may have limited impact on increasing the overall revenue brought in by exports. However, the work of the World Trade Organization (WTO) over the last two decades has led to a decrease in international trade barriers, allowing for more open and free trade. As a result, a weak exchange rate strategy may have a greater chance of success in the current global trade environment.
evaluation: Q: How can the strength of demand overseas and at home affect the effectiveness of a weak exchange rate strategy?
A: The effectiveness of a weak exchange rate strategy in rectifying a current account deficit depends on the strength of demand overseas and at home. If demand overseas is weak due to a recession in major trading economies, the fall in export prices resulting from a weak exchange rate may not significantly increase demand for exports. Consequently, export revenues may not increase, leaving the current account deficit unaffected or even worsening it. Similarly, if demand at home is strong, such as during an economic boom, despite the rise in import prices caused by a weak exchange rate, demand for imports may remain high as consumers continue to “suck in” imports. This can result in import expenditure not decreasing and the current account deficit remaining unaffected or even worsening. The effectiveness of a weak exchange rate strategy is contingent on the prevailing demand conditions in both domestic and overseas markets.